SciELO - Scientific Electronic Library Online

 
 número89Capitalismo y minería global: perspectivas latinoamericanas, 1500-1914 índice de autoresíndice de materiabúsqueda de artículos
Home Pagelista alfabética de revistas  

Servicios Personalizados

Revista

Articulo

Indicadores

Links relacionados

  • En proceso de indezaciónCitado por Google
  • No hay articulos similaresSimilares en SciELO
  • En proceso de indezaciónSimilares en Google

Compartir


Historia Crítica

versión impresa ISSN 0121-1617

hist.crit.  no.89 Bogotá jul./sep. 2023  Epub 10-Jul-2023

https://doi.org/10.7440/histcrit89.2023.01 

Dossier

Capitalisms of the “Global South” (c. 10th to 19th Centuries) - Old and New Contributions and Debates*

Capitalismos del “Sur Global” (c. siglos x-xix) - Viejos y nuevos aportes y debates

Capitalismos do “Sul global” (c. séculos 10-19): contribuições e debates antigos e novos

Kaveh Yazdani** 

Constanza Castro*** 

**He received his Ph.D. degree from the University of Osnabrück (summa cum laude). In 2015, he was granted the Prince Dr. Sabbar Farman-Farmaian Fellowship at the International Institute of Social History (IISH) in Amsterdam and a Mellon Postdoctoral Research Fellowship at the Centre for Indian Studies in Africa (CISA) in Johannesburg, South Africa. He taught economic and social history courses between 2017 and 2020 at the University of Bielefeld, attended as Visiting Professor of Global Economic and Social History at the University of Vienna in 2020 and works as Assistant Professor at the University of Connecticut (United States) since 2021. In 2022, he obtained a residential visiting scholarship at the Max Planck Institute for the History of Science in Berlin. His recent publications include Capitalisms: Towards a Global History, Oxford University Press: Delhi 2020 (co-edited with Dilip Menon), doi https://academic.oup.com/book/33687 and India, Modernity and the Great Divergence: Mysore and Gujarat (17th to 19th Century), Leiden/Boston: Brill 2017. kaveh.yazdani@uconn.edu

***She received her Ph.D. in History from Columbia University (With distinction). In 2011 she obtained the Social Science Research Council (ssrc-acls), International Dissertation Research Fellowship, and also won the Whiting Foundation Fellowship from Columbia University. Presently she is an Assistant Professor in the Department of History and Geography at Universidad de los Andes in Bogotá. She is a member of the Global Urban History Project Board of Directors and an affiliate member of the Center for Spatial and Textual Analysis (cesta), at Stanford University. Her recent publications included “The Enclosure of the Ejidos of Bogotá: Imperial Wars and the End of Common Lands in Colonial New Granada.” (Journal of Urban History 48, n.º4, 760-781, https://doi.org/10.1177/00961442211041972) and “Writing the liberal city: Historical consciousness and literary visions of economic change Bogotá 1849-1870,” (Textual Practice) (Forthcoming). ccastrobc@uniandes.edu.co


Abstract:

Objective/Context:

The purpose of this article is first to contextualize the concept of the “Global South.” Then, we offer an overview of classical and new historiographies of capitalism(s) of the “Global South.” We focus on works that examine the period between roughly the 10th and 19th centuries, and further explain how we understand and periodize capitalism. Lastly, we introduce the contributions to this special issue.

Methodology:

This review is based on a holistic and non-Eurocentric Marxian approach, emphasizing the importance of both internal and external factors, global entanglements and uneven development when studying regional dynamics. We also underline the relevance of both connections and comparisons in understanding and analyzing the genesis and rise of global capitalism(s). In other words, we highlight multifaceted forces at work that may be conceived of in terms of a global dialectical conjuncture.

Originality:

This is one of the few existing articles that pulls together and briefly outlines the different existing trends in writing the histories of capitalism(s) in the “Global South” before the advent of the 20th century. We discuss developments in China, India, the “Islamicate” world, Latin America, the relationship between modern plantation slavery and capitalism as well the “Great Divergence” debate. In doing so, we identify a “global turn” in recent historiographies of capitalism(s).

Conclusions:

We suggest that the prevalent binary narratives -either embracing or rejecting the (pre-)capitalist nature of societies, commercial practices and production sites in the “Global South”-do not do justice to the complexity of historical dynamics. Furthermore, many studies lack nuances and do not adequately consider multilinear processes, entanglements between the local and global and shifting multipolar centers of development. More often than not, academics also neglect spatio-temporal specificities, transitional periods between -or the hybrid coexistence of- different modes of production, that is, developments which should neither be reduced to predominantly capitalist nor pre-capitalist relations, processes and structures. We also argue that a return to the concept of totality helps to transcend the oversimplified assumptions and analyses of dominant historical accounts.

Keywords:  Africa; Asia; capitalism; “Global South”; Latin America

Resumen:

Objetivo/Contexto:

Con este articulo tenemos varios propósitos. El primero, es contextualizar el concepto de “Sur Global”. Luego, señalamos algunos elementos claves de las historiografías clásicas y recientes sobre los capitalismos del “Sur Global” entre los siglos x y xix aproximadamente, y explicamos en detalle cómo entendemos y periodizamos el capitalismo. Por último, presentamos las contribuciones de este dossier.

Metodología:

Esta revisión historiográfica tiene un enfoque marxista, holístico y no eurocéntrico, que reconoce la importancia de analizar factores internos y externos, entrecruzamientos globales, desigualdades regionales, conexiones y posibles comparaciones, -o lo que podemos llamar coyuntura dialéctica global- en el estudio de las dinámicas regionales en el surgimiento y ascenso de los capitalismos globales.

Originalidad:

Este es uno de los pocos artículos que reúne varias de las diferentes miradas sobre las historias de(los) capitalismo(s) surgidos en el “Sur Global” antes del siglo xx. Analizamos la evolución del capitalismo en China, India, las regiones con mayorías musulmanas, y América Latina, así como la relación entre el capitalismo y la esclavitud moderna de las plantaciones, y el debate sobre la “Gran Divergencia”. Al hacerlo, encontramos evidente un “giro global” en las recientes historiografías del capitalismo.

Conclusiones:

Sugerimos que las narrativas binarias predominantes - que aceptan o rechazan la naturaleza (pre)capitalista de las sociedades del “Sur Global”, así como de sus prácticas comerciales y de sus lugares de producción- no hacen justicia a la complejidad de las dinámicas históricas, y de las coyunturas globales. Muchos estudios carecen de matices y no consideran adecuadamente procesos multilineales, entrecruzamientos complejos entre lo local y lo global, y cambios en los centros multipolares de desarrollo socioeconómico. Con frecuencia, los académicos ignoran también, las especificidades espaciotemporales y los periodos transicionales o de coexistencia entre modos de producción, que no pueden reducirse a relaciones, procesos y estructuras capitalistas o precapitalistas únicamente. También argumentamos que volver a una concepción de totalidad ayuda a superar los supuestos y los análisis excesivamente simplificados de los relatos históricos dominantes.

Palabras clave: África; América Latina; Asia; capitalismo; “Sur Global”.

Resumo:

Objetivo/Contexto:

Com este artigo, temos vários objetivos. O primeiro é contextualizar o conceito de “Sul global”. Em seguida, apontamos alguns elementos-chave das historiografias clássicas e recentes sobre os capitalismos do “Sul global” entre os séculos 10 e 19, aproximadamente, e explicamos detalhadamente sobre como entendemos e periodizamos o capitalismo. Por fim, apresentamos as contribuições deste dossiê.

Metodologia:

Esta revisão historiográfica adota uma abordagem marxista, holística e não eurocêntrica, reconhecendo a importância de analisar fatores internos e externos, interseções globais, desigualdades regionais, conexões e possíveis comparações, o que podemos chamar conjuntura dialética global, ao estudar a dinâmica regional no surgimento e na ascensão dos capitalismos globais.

Originalidade:

Este é um dos poucos artigos que reúne várias das diferentes visões sobre as histórias do(s) capitalismo(s) que surgiram no “Sul global” antes do século 20. Analisamos a evolução do capitalismo na China, na Índia, nas regiões de maioria muçulmana e na América Latina, bem como a relação entre o capitalismo e a escravidão moderna nas plantações, e o debate sobre a “Grande divergência”. Ao fazer isso, consideramos evidente uma “virada global” nas historiografias recentes do capitalismo.

Conclusões:

Sugerimos que as narrativas binárias predominantes - aceitar ou rejeitar a natureza (pré)capitalista das sociedades do “Sul global”, bem como suas práticas comerciais e locais de produção - não fazem justiça à complexidade das dinâmicas históricas e das conjunturas globais. Muitos estudos carecem de nuances e não consideram adequadamente os processos multilineares, as complexas interligações entre o local e o global, e as mudanças nos centros multipolares de desenvolvimento socioeconômico. Com frequência, os estudiosos também ignoram as especificidades espaço-temporais e os períodos de transição ou a coexistência entre os modos de produção, que não podem ser reduzidos apenas às relações, aos processos e às estruturas capitalistas ou pré-capitalistas. Também argumentamos que o retorno a uma concepção de totalidade ajuda a superar as suposições e análises excessivamente simplificadas das narrativas históricas dominantes.

Palavras-chave:  África; América Latina; Ásia; capitalismo; “Sul global”.

Introduction

The history of capitalism is a double-edged sword, replete with ambivalent contradictions. On the one hand, in the course of the 19th-century, industrial capitalism did away with Malthusian traps, made possible by the great leap in techno-scientific innovation, including the massive use of fossil fuels. Capitalist industrialization facilitated the spread of previously unmatched progress in medicine, sanitation, public health, production and food processing. Since the late 19th-century, capitalist productive forces created the conditions for more and more material comfort and wealth. This favored an unparalleled global rise in population, living standards and leisure time. In conjunction with socio-political dynamics, industrial capitalism enabled the amplified provision of households with electricity, refrigeration, running water, private bathrooms, cooking facilities and home appliances. It also permitted hitherto unseen world-wide transformations in transportation, communication, infrastructure, logistics, scientific management, organization, institutions, coordination and distribution, as well as the expedited global circulation and accumulation of knowledge, cultures, resources, products and services. To a considerable extent, those advancements resulted from the increased employment of constant capital (means and materials used to produce commodities and services) and variable capital (investment in wages). The former included steam power, railways, steamships, automobiles, the telegraph, the camera, and, by the 20th century, the use of nuclear energy, the dissemination of radios and televisions, the introduction of airplanes, satellites, the internet, mobile phones, robotization and the first steps towards artificial intelligence. These developments led to the consolidation of sustained economic growth, increased productivity, the intensified compression of time and space, and a doubling of the average life expectancy in many regions of the world.1

On the other hand, the capitalist class and power relations unfolding from the 16th century onwards are largely responsible for expropriating and exploiting countless members of the subaltern classes the world over. Indeed, capitalist elites, nations and empires have committed horrendous crimes through domestic state repression and colonial and imperialist subjugation. Meanwhile, contemporary world capitalism seems to be in a deep state of crisis, not least due to prevailing tendencies towards financialization and monopolization, diminishing real wages in several regions and occupational sectors across the globe, the unprecedented gap between rich and poor, including widespread super-exploitation in the “Global South,” the lingering dangers of nuclear extinction, new forms of violence, coercion, surveillance, oppression and alienation, the artificialization of the lifeworld, the socio-ecological and cultural effects of reification and commodity fetishism as well as the devastating and seemingly irreparable environmental destruction that capitalist development entails. As Nancy Fraser has recently diagnosed, echoing Marx, at the present time, capital is more and more growing into “a serpent that eats its own tail, it cannibalizes its own conditions of possibility.”2 The contemporary rise of global fascism and social malaise is paralleled by the spiraling contest for a precise characterization of the present stage of socio-economic development. Which form of capitalism prevails? Is it “monopoly-finance,” “neoliberal,” “political,” “digital,” “rentier” or a hybrid simultaneity of varieties of capitalism? Some, like Yanis Varoufakis, even believe that we have already transitioned into a post-capitalist “techno-feudal” economy.3 At any rate, we seem to have reached a critical juncture or tipping point and, currently, the destructive consequences of capitalist developments are most drastically felt in the “Global South.” The ever-increasing calamities of “catastrophe” and “cannibal capitalism” make it even more relevant to trace the historical evolution of these processes in order to better understand how we got where we are in the present day. Yet, the genesis and rise of capitalism are more often than not written from the standpoint of the “Global North.” Many regions in the “Global South” have received relatively short shrift in academic writings on the history of capitalism, while its peoples have often been reduced to mere victims or portrayed as plain recipients of capitalism with little agency and overall impact. But what do we mean by invoking the term “Global South”?

1. The “Global South”

Especially from the turn of the 1960s, the label “Global South” attained some currency. However, it was only after the collapse of the Soviet Union that the term began to gain increased traction among academics and activists, and gradually supplanted the then seemingly obsolete designations of “periphery,” “developing,” “underdeveloped” or “Third World” which all somewhat derived from a “center-periphery” model of historical understanding.4 In the course of the 21st century, notably during the past ten years, the rise of the concept has been steep and inexorable. Some have used it when referring to commonalities of otherwise very different world regions, sharing similar structures and processes of socio-economic inequality, primarily resulting from global capitalism. As Marlea Clarke notes, the “Global South” is not “strictly a geographical category but a political economy characterization.”5 According to Nour Dados and Raewyn Connell, the notion of the “Global South” also “marks a shift from a focus on development or cultural difference toward an emphasis on geopolitical relations of power.” For them, the term “Global South” encapsulates “an entire history of colonialism, neo-imperialism, and differential economic and social change through which large inequalities in living standard, life expectancy, and access to resources are maintained.”6 Under the influence of postcolonial theory, the “Global South” has also been used to question Eurocentric epistemologies. For authors such as Anibal Quijano or Raewyn Connell, the term makes visible historical and global processes and forms of knowledge in motion, originating in non-Western geographical and historical contexts.7 The concept of the “Global South” has also become a political slogan in academia and international activism that “draws attention to global struggles and solidarities” among different peoples sharing experiences of inequality in contemporary global capitalism.8 In this vein, Anne Garland Mahler argues that the “Global South” refers mainly to a political consciousness fundamental to theorizing contemporary hegemony and resistance.9

As with many overarching terms such as the “East” or the “Third World,” the idea of the “Global South” -not least due to its vagueness, differing definitions and homogenizing tendencies-has its problems and drawbacks. Some consider it a static and ahistorical notion that tries to fix constantly changing geopolitical processes. Others see it as some version of a redemptive “Third World” narrative that is now politically exhausted, while some critics of the term dismiss it as a watchword that has been captured by “institutions dominated by the North and the global financial sector” in such a way that, as Vijay Prashad contends, it promotes “neoliberalism with Southern characteristics”.10

Despite the anachronism of the concept as to the periods that have been covered in this special issue, and, for the lack of a more all-inclusive term, we hold on to the use of the “Global South” in order to demarcate Europe and North America from the regions under examination, namely, parts of Asia, Africa, Latin America, the Caribbean and Pacific Islands.11 Indeed, the term helps to understand, analyze and subsume global socio-economic processes in distinct non-Western geographical and historical settings under a single terminological umbrella. But, we use the label “Global South” hesitantly, as the quotation marks are meant to signal.

2. The “Global South” in Classical Histories of Capitalism

As early as the late 19th and early 20th century, venerated scholars such as Karl Marx, Dadabhai Naoroji, John A. Hobson, Vladimir. I. Lenin and Rosa Luxemburg declared that the colonial system was central in promoting capitalist development in the West and underdevelopment in the colonized world. Concurrently, to this very day, the shadows of Marx and Max Weber loom large and continue to bar historians from recognizing non-Western tendencies towards, or elements and forms of (modern) indigenous capitalisms prior to the advent of Europe’s global politico-economic preeminence between the 19th and late 20th centuries. Weber’s dualist analysis entailed that Catholicism -and, by implication, the Iberian mindset dominant in Latin America- was seen as “feudal” and somewhat antithetical to the development of modern capitalism.12 But he was even more articulate when delineating the reasons why it was only in the West that modern, rational, bourgeois and industrial capitalism could evolve:

It is only in the Occident that rational capitalist enterprises with fixed capital, free labour and the rational specialisation and combination of work can be found, with purely commercial distribution effected on the basis of capitalist economy. Which means: the capitalist form of formally purely voluntaristic organisation of labour as the typical and ruling form through which the needs of the broad mass are met, with the expropriation of workers from the means of production, and the appropriation of enterprises to those who hold securities. Only here is there public credit taking the form of government securities; commercialisation; the issue of securities and financial operations as the object of rational enterprise; stock market trading in commodities and securities; “markets” for money and for capital; monopolistic associations as a form of economically rational organisation for the production of goods in enterprises (and not only trade in goods).13

A couple of years before, the now almost forgotten German political economist Gustav Ruhland offered a much less rigorous but also less binary exposition. He did not adequately define the term and (similar to Theodor Mommsen and his student Max Weber) saw traces of capitalism as far back as antiquity. Nonetheless, he was among the earliest, if not the first, to argue that modernity -what he called the “new age” (neue Zeit) following the Middle Ages- was not only characterized by the introduction of humanism, the “reception” of roman law, different inventions, including the art of printing and the “discovery” of new world regions. But principally, as he averred, modernity was heralded by the extension of the “money economy” and the European adoption of “capitalism from the Islamic Orient” between the 10th and 12th centuries.14 Hence, by the early 20th century, some of the preliminary foundations had been laid for studying the history of capitalism through both a comparative and connected lens. By the 1920s, scholars in Japan, China and India too were already grappling with indigenous “sprouts” and potentialities of capitalist development.15 In 1922, for example, the Bengali scholar and revolutionary M. N. Roy -who founded both the Mexican Communist Party (1917) and the Communist Party of India in 1920 (Tashkent group) -proclaimed that 18th century India had already entered “commercial” or “mercantile capitalism” and that, in the absence of colonial rule, India “under a normal course of development would have led up to modern capitalist industrialism.”16 Similarly, in 1939, Mao Zedong argued that the “development of commodity economy in Chinese feudal society had already given birth to the sprouts of capitalism; had it not been for the influence of foreign capitalism, China would have developed slowly into a capitalist society.”17

The question of whether 17th to 19th century plantation slaveries in the Caribbean, Latin America or the antebellum South were capitalist or not has equally been a bone of contention for at least 125 years. In Capital, Vol. 1 (1867), Marx had already alluded to capitalist elements in 19th-century plantation slavery and considered colonialism and slavery as “chief moments” of Western Europe’s and especially England’s processes of original accumulation -that is, the transition period from a pre-capitalist to a capitalist mode of production.18 But, in 1899, Karl Kautsky designated antebellum Southern plantations as “pre-capitalist,” while, in 1902, Werner Sombart argued that the late 18th- and 19th century stage of “high capitalism” (Hochkapitalismus) was enhanced by the exploitation of slave labor.19 In 1915, Lenin explicitly characterized US plantations as pre-capitalist, whereas Weber presumed that the US South consisted of “capitalist slavery”.20

In the late 1920s, Henri Sée was among the first generation of historians to argue that French West Indian colonies played a pivotal role in the process of capital accumulation in France and a few years later, Gaston Martin also asserted that the slave trade contributed to capitalist development and early industrialization in 18th century Nantes.21 In 1934, W.E.B. Du Bois stated that: “I look upon the development of the African slave trade through chartered companies as the beginning of modern international capitalism and imperialism.”22 In 1939, he reiterated that “the basis of the English trade, on which capitalism was erected, was Negro labor.”23 Especially the in-depth works of C.L.R. James and Eric Williams popularized the assumption that slavery contributed to capitalist development in France and England respectively. Furthermore, the former also explicitly emphasized the capitalist features of modern plantation slavery itself.24

The term “colonial mode of production” was probably coined around the early 20th century. Nonetheless, since the late 1930s, and particularly between the 1950s and 1970s, it was in analyzing colonized regions in Asia and Africa, especially India, but also Latin America, that this label was increasingly used to distinguish dependent colonial from independent metropolitan socio-economic trajectories.25 In 1949, Argentine historian Sergio Bagú challenged the consensus among Latin American Marxists regarding the supposed feudal nature of the colonial economy. He argued that feudalism and capitalism did not have to be “irreconcilable extremes” because elements of both a “feudal configuration” and a “capitalist configuration” had coexisted in the colonial economic regime.26 In 1950, historian Jan Bazant questioned this dual version in favor of a capitalist vision of the colonial economy. In a controversial article, he argued that Mexican farms growing wheat or corn were capitalist since they were linked to internal markets, required considerable fixed capital and produced commodities on a large scale.27 According to his analysis, there were only a few existing “feudal survivals” within Mexican labor relations in an otherwise capitalist economy.

After the Second World War, in the midst of the reconstruction of Europe and processes of decolonization, these interpretations contributed to igniting a debate on the nature and causes of “development” and “underdevelopment.” During this period, “Latin American structuralism” made a major contribution to the field of development economics. In a document that became “the manifesto” of Latin America’s first “development theory,” Argentine economist Raúl Prebisch challenged the orthodoxies of modernization theory by proposing the “center-periphery” model to describe asymmetric relations between Latin American economies and centers in the industrialized “Global North.”28 According to him, Latin America’s recurrent balance-of-payments crises placed severe constraints on the region’s economic growth and acted as a bottleneck in the process of industrialization. From 1949 onwards, the Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (cepal), led by Prebisch, developed a systemic theory that dismissed previous evolutionary visions of modernization. For this Commission, the region’s “underdevelopment” was not the consequence of a feudal economy that could be overcome if following the path of modernization but a result of its incorporation “as an integral, exploited partner in the world’s capitalist development”.29 Underdevelopment, they argued, was due to the deterioration of the terms of trade of peripheral primary producers. To reduce dependency, they proposed the transition from primary export-led growth to import-substituting industrialization through active state intervention. With the center-periphery model, economists from postwar Latin America shifted to a global view of colonial history to explain the role, albeit unequal, of Latin America in the growth and consolidation of the capitalist world economy.30 Indeed, they examined the problem of development and capitalism from the margins of the global capitalist economy, and influenced the political agenda of the so-called periphery for several decades.31

In the 1950s, a debate about the role of Chinese commerce in “the transition from feudalism to capitalism” caught on among Marxists in both China and Japan and, by the late 1950s, some Western scholars of China had also taken up the debate.32 In the early 1960s, several Indian and Soviet historians revived notions of “merchant” or “indigenous capitalism” in the context of Mughal India.33 By the mid- and late 1960s, some Western and Arab historians posited that even before the ascent of Italian city-states, merchant capitalism had already grown in parts of West Asia and Egypt.34

The success of the Chinese and Cuban revolutions, the rise of nationalist movements in various colonies, the limits of state-led economic plans, visible asymmetries within and between dependent countries-particularly compared to those who had achieved some level of industrialization-and the ascent of authoritarian regimes in Latin America’s southern cone, impacted contemporary ideas about capitalism in Latin America. Some intellectuals even questioned whether Latin America could achieve development at all, given its peripheral position since its insertion in the global economy. In a book published in 1969, Carlos Henrique Cardoso and Enzo Faletto conceded the irreversibility of “dependent development.” But they also saw the possibility of some “associated dependent development” in countries in which both domestic ownership of industry was substantial and some outward-oriented groups managed to form coalitions with other like-minded groups to promote policies favoring some autonomous development.35 Other theoreticians, such as André Gunder Frank, proclaimed that a reformist approach that did not break with global capitalism would inevitably fail to achieve economic development. By arguing that the only way out of underdevelopment was revolution, he was participating in a long debate about the character of the “colonial mode of production” that, since the first decades of the 20th century, guided political praxis.36 For some scholars, if colonization transferred a feudal model from the center to the periphery, a bourgeois revolution was the first step to get out of underdevelopment. For others, if Latin America had been part of the capitalist world since the 16th century, to overcome underdevelopment, a socialist revolution was a historical necessity.

As early as 1890, Germán Ave-Lallemant, an engineer and member of the Argentine Socialist Party, wrote that “feudal” economic and legal relations prevented the formation of a bourgeois society that could have “completely penetrated the social organization and remodel it according to the [requirements of those] times.”37 In the 1920s, José Carlos Mariátegui indicated that large and unproductive landholdings persisted in Perú as late as the 20th century because the bourgeoisie had not removed the “feudal structure” of the colonial economy after the wars of independence.38 During the 1940s, Marxist and liberal intellectuals alike continued to invoke a feudal-like past to explain Latin America’s hampered modernization.39 Intellectuals on the left, like Avé-Lallemant and Mariátegui, advocated the idea of a bourgeois revolution as a means to overcome underdevelopment. Liberals who accepted the “feudal roots” of underdevelopment echoed modernization theories and the perception of Latin America as traditional, resistant to change, and non-integrated into the market economy. To achieve modernity, political and cultural changes were assumed to be the path to follow. For A. G. Frank, who viewed Latin America as part of a capitalist world order ever since the beginning of the Spanish conquest, the only remaining viable alternative after the failure of state-led development policies was a socialist revolution. His book, written from the vantage point of “dependency theory,” incentivized a renewed debate about the “colonial mode of production” in the 1970s.

Against the backdrop of Frank and other developmentalists’ theoretical shortcomings, Marxist historians, sociologists and economists pointed out the need to “return to Marx” in order to avoid the uncritical transfer of a European concept such as feudalism to Latin America. Also, to shift from the limiting debate of modes of production towards broader colonial relations, and move from the domination of mercantile capital to the importance of productive capital.40 Juan Carlos Garavaglia and Ernesto Laclau argued that colonial Latin American economies were better understood as a combination of different modes of production and should therefore be defined as non-consolidated social formations. This idea derived from a Marxian distinction that Laclau drew between “economic system” (or “social formation”) and mode of production. The basis of this approach stemmed from his definition of mode of production. Returning to a Marxian understanding of modes of production, Laclau did not merely rest upon the sphere of commodity exchange, which can exist in both feudalism and capitalism, but his analysis also comprised the sphere of production. Influenced by Louis Althusser and Etienne Balibar, he argued that distinct modes of production could coexist in a single social formation. In the case of Brazil, for example, he identified an “indissoluble unity […] between the maintenance of feudal backwardness at the one extreme and the apparent progress of the bourgeois dynamism at the other.” “The Brazilian reality,” he asserted, “like that of the other countries of the Third World, is that the ‘feudal mode of production’ in agriculture is precisely at the service of imperialism rather than antagonistically in contradiction with it.”41

The Argentine historian Carlos Sempat Assadourian also criticized Frank and the defenders of the theory of a “colonial capitalist” Latin America. For this author, colonial Latin America was in a mercantile phase, which could not lead to industrial capitalism. In other words, “the system of production for the market and the dominance of commercial capital in Latin America does not dissolve but rather imposes feudal forms, since these allow a level of surplus appropriation at maximum intensity.”42 Capitalism, according to Assadourian, had only taken hold in Latin America by the 20th century, but the complexity of the colonial period could not be explained by the “simple formula” of feudalism or capitalism. Assadourian also criticized the imposition of theories at the expense of historical analyses because history was the base of political praxis. Since 1974, in his three-volume magnum opus The Modern World-System, Immanuel Wallerstein attempted to change the emphasis of this drawn-out discussion. Recognizing the relevance of dependency theory, he was of the opinion that the most important problem of the time was to trace and analyze the intensification of a global division of labor that, from the 16th century on, required different labor regimes in different regions of the capitalist “world-system.”43

Other debates, also originating in Latin America, paved the way for the formulation of “decolonial thought” in the 1990s.44 In the 1960s, authors within the dependency tradition, such as Pablo González Casanova, Julio Cotler and Rodolfo Stavenhagen, had already incorporated the category of “race” in their analyses of “internal colonialism.”45 As part of a larger Marxist critique of development ideologies, González Casanova used this concept to describe the racialized economic dimension of relations between the dominant Mexican mestizos and subordinated “American Indians.” However, we could trace the discussion about “race” and social class in postcolonial Latin America back to the Marxist approach of Peruvian scholar J.C. Mariátegui.46 His 1929 article “The indigenous problem in Latin America,” among other works, were later described by Aníbal Quijano as “moments of theoretical subversion against Eurocentrism,” necessary to understand the idea of “race” as the “basis of a whole new system of social domination.”47

In conjunction with some of the aforementioned works, between the 1940s and 1980s, a great number of renowned scholars, way too many to be listed here, made pathbreaking contributions that provided the grounds for the subsequent rise of global comparative and/or connected socio-economic histories.48 By and large, however, a substantial number of analyses on a) non-Western “buds,” barriers and potentialities of capitalist development and b) the features and implications of modern plantation slavery have one thing in common, namely, the dichotomous binaries that they repeatedly draw. More often than not, historians either fully embrace or widely reject the (pre-)capitalist nature of countries, commercial practices and production sites under study. Indeed, several academics do not sufficiently take heed of nuances, multilinear processes, entanglements between the local and global and shifting multipolar centers of development. They also neglect transitional, hybrid or spatio-temporal specificities that should neither be reduced to predominantly capitalist nor pre-capitalist relations, processes and structures.

3. The “Global South” in the New Histories of Capitalism(s)

The noun capitalism originated in the late 18th or early 19th-century and proliferated from the mid-19th century onwards. It first appeared in French, English and Spanish and soon after in German.49 Yet, the term “capitalisms” in the plural (capitalismes in French or capitalismos in Spanish) was hardly used before the 1900s.50 It gained currency in the course of the 20th century, and there was a notable rise in the employment of “capitalisms” from the late 1980s, followed by comparative studies on “varieties of capitalism” since the 1990s.51 Besides, since the mid-1990s and especially in the past 15 years, an increased interest in global histories of commercial and early industrial capitalism(s) has emerged.52 To a certain extent, we may even go as far as identifying a “global turn” in the historiography of capitalism in recent times.

In contrast to prior global narratives, notably Immanuel Wallerstein’s highly influential school of world-systems analysis-which inaccurately retrojected global European supremacy to the 16th century-many more recent global histories envision the pre-industrial world in less Eurocentric and more or less polycentric terms. At the same time, since the late 1990s, academics working on issues of global (comparative) history shifted away from understanding the genesis of capitalism and instead turned to explain the reasons behind the “rise of the West” and the Industrial Revolution that caused the “Great Divergence” between “the West and the rest.” As a matter of fact, beginning with the publication of Kenneth Pomeranz’s The Great Divergence (2000), there has been an explosion of articles and books on the sources of Western industrial breakthroughs and global domination.53 Although this booming literature of the past 25 years has enormously enriched our knowledge and empirical basis, many existing studies suffer from serious methodological flaws and theoretical limitations. In other words,

[…] the lack of holistic approaches or what Marx - under the influence of Hegel - termed totality, is the greatest shortcoming in current debates on the Great Divergence [...] What caused the Great Divergence was a combination of convoluted factors, a global dialectical conjuncture based on a concatenation of intra-European, extra-European and entangled, long-term, short-term, continuous and contingent factors.54

The rationale of this special issue is to add to the growing non-Eurocentric body of literature by focusing on histories of capitalisms from the “Global South”. As with all works, there are also several omissions in the present volume. Indeed, we regret not having been able to include a number of economically vibrant areas such as parts of West and South East Asia, the Ottoman Empire, Safavid and Qajar Persia, the well-connected regions of Latin America, and countries such as Egypt, Japan and Korea.55 What is more, we would have liked to include more articles on the relationship between pre-20th century capitalism and the problems of gender, “race” and ecology.56 Nonetheless, we did our best to assemble a dozen of articles by leading historians in their respective fields, working on the history of capitalism from non-Western perspectives. Not surprisingly, however, the contributors to this special issue also have different and sometimes contradictory conceptions of or approaches towards capitalism.

As to recently published edited volumes on the global history of capitalism, The Cambridge History of Capitalism (2014) is probably the best-known example. Despite its many merits, the rationale-especially of its first volume-is not only ahistorical as it abets the “naturalization” of capitalism by opening the narrative in ancient Babylonia. But it also leaves out a number of regions and issues that certainly deserve more attention and scrutiny.57 In the past decade or so, edited volumes on the longue durée histories of capitalisms from more or less global viewpoints have markedly proliferated.58 But, some of those who have made efforts to historicize the capitalist mode of production -notably adherents of “Political Marxism”- remain rigid and Eurocentric in both their methodological approach as well as spatio-temporal coverage. They often see the “origin” of capitalism in contingent terms and generally believe that, until the 19th-century, capitalism had hardly developed outside of England.59 Historia Crítica’s Capitalisms of the “Global South” volume is a deliberate attempt to counter the spatio-temporal frameworks of some of the aforementioned types of (neo-)classical, (neo-)Marxist, world-systems or post-colonial approaches. At the same time, we recognize that capitalism spreads unevenly, depending on the specific countries, localities and areas in question. Indeed, more than a few regions between the 16th and 19th centuries were neither predominantly based on feudal, Asiatic, tributary or capitalist modes of production nor fully part of the growing world economy. Yet, a number of areas went through transitional periods where different modes of production coexisted alongside each other.

4. Defining and Periodizing Capitalism

What is capitalism and when did it emerge? Needless to say, there is little consensus on this question. Partly as a result, in the past decade, academics who work on the history of capitalism, notably adherents of the “New History of Capitalism,” have increasingly abstained from explaining what they mean by the term. For our part, we embrace a Marxian definition and understand capitalism as a historically evolving socio-economic formation; a socio-economic system and politico-institutional order that, despite its “core essentials,” is versatile and subject to ever-changing processes in motion.

Capitalism is geared to generate endless exchange and surplus value, capital accumulation, valorization, profit, interest and rent-seeking -generally to the benefit of a comparatively tiny number of capitalists, corporations and/or states; and this, on an ever-expanding inward (e.g., the commodification of the lifeworld) and outward (e.g., imperialism) scale. Therefore, capitalism requires a predominantly capitalist legal-administrative framework and a supportive state. It needs property rights in the means of production, the prevalence of impersonal, competitive and/or oligopolistic markets, generalized market dependence and the prevailing allocation through markets. Capitalism also entails a monetary system, including financial institutions, credit, interest and debt, the constant transformation of the productive forces to increase productivity and, furthermore, well-established entrepreneurship.

The consolidation of capitalism presupposes and necessitates an expanding world economy, (planetary) resource extraction, as well as asymmetrical (global) power and class relations. In turn, these movements have been historically secured by uneven and varying relations of force -e.g., dispossession, coerced labor and anthropocentric, gendered, racial, colonial and imperialist forms of domination (though not all are logically necessary for expanded capitalist reproduction). These processes are safeguarded by the hegemonic ideological superstructure of the bourgeoisie and/or capitalist elites.

One of the main pillars of Marxian definitions of capitalism comprises “generalized commodity production.” In other words, the circuit in which commodities are produced by other commodities as both sources and results of capital to relentlessly accumulate more money capital on an ever-expanding magnitude (m - c ... p ... c’ - m’).60 As against orthodox Marxist presumptions, however, surplus value can be produced by both formally free and unfree forms of labor relations.61

Concurrently, it is only the prevalence of formally free wage labor and the capital relation that seem to be capable of engendering consumer societies, including expanding consumer markets and the necessary “human capital” formation involved in processes of ever-increasing valorization, commodification (of inputs and outputs such as raw materials, goods, labor, land) and capitalization. The factors mentioned above were all essential ingredients that made the development of industrial capitalism(s) in the 20th and 21st centuries possible in the first place.62

On the other hand, commercial capitalism-which was the prevalent form of capitalism until the mid-19th century-is defined as “a combination of Smithian growth and social relations of exchange and production dominated by a merchant class that reinvests portions of profit into commerce and/or a certain degree of commodity production.”63

The development of capitalism underwent different historical stages and phases of growth. During the period of nascent mercantile capitalism, roughly spanning the 13th to 15th centuries, merchant and usurious capital increasingly made inroads into the still dominant pre-capitalist socio-economic formations (Italian city-states being the exemplary case).64 Between the 16th and 18th centuries, commercial and entrepreneurial capitalisms more and more broke through the pre-capitalist structures of advanced Afro-Eurasian societies and political economies. Amongst others, this development was enhanced by long-distance trade, colonization, the putting-out and dadani systems,65 slave plantations as well as the rise of workshops and manufactures. These, increasingly produced exchange values, partly through the formal subsumption (subordination) of labor under capital and the extraction of absolute surplus value. As against conventional wisdom, this process occurred not only in core regions of Western Europe, but also in parts of South and East Asia and, to a lesser extent, in some areas of West Asia and North Africa. Furthermore, this was the period of the so-called original accumulation that Marx powerfully delineated in his brilliant chapters of Part Eight, Capital, Vol. 1.66

Some of the determining factors that distinguished Western European capitalisms from those of most other parts of the world lay in the formers’ rise of bourgeois societies, the capitalist transformation of the state, statecraft, institutions and social relations, a peculiar type of techno-scientific and intellectual dynamism, the prevalent European valorization and exploitation of overseas colonies, the systematic appropriation of extra-European humans, knowledge, resources and know-how along with several other contingent and structural conjunctures and processes.67 Eventually, this transition period ushered in industrial capitalism (from 1760 onwards) while devastating the livelihoods of millions and millions of subordinated Europeans, and, particularly Native Americans, Africans and Asians in the course of that passage. Between the 16th and 19th centuries, the capitalist system was in the making while the Americas and large parts of Asia and Africa were-at different moments in time-violently drawn into an emerging capitalist world economy that, by the 19th-century, was almost entirely dominated by European powers.

5. Contributions to Historia Crítica’s Special Issue: “Capitalisms of the ‘Global South’”

In the past decades, there has been an increased interest in the history of capitalism in West Asia and North Africa.68 In a related interview that we conducted with Richard Bulliet for this special issue, he argues that the “caravan trade,” which significantly expanded between 300 BCE and 1300 CE, connected and revolutionized commercial, social and cultural relations in large parts of “Islamicate” West Asia, Central and South Asia as well as North Africa. As he asserts, this partly also explains the differences from other world regions that hardly acquired any animal portage, including most pre-Columbian Americas and equatorial Africa. Bulliet compares the Asio-African caravan trade to the European merchant capitalism that permeated maritime trade in the late Middle Ages. In short, it was especially the camel caravan trade that made the overland bulk transport of heavy goods and commodities economically viable.

There is also an expanding literature on the role of American silver in the emergence of global capitalism between the 16th and 18th centuries.69 Questioning its limits, James Torres’ article is an invitation to go beyond the silver-centered narratives that have dominated the history of mining in Spanish America, to include new venues of research that would open up the dialogue with practitioners of the history of capitalism. He highlights the importance of studying both non-precious metals and non-metallic minerals; bimetallism; microeconomic dynamics of mining; and the enormous ecological impact of mining in modern times, which have not been integrated into the broader studies of capitalist development in Latin America. Torres argues that shifting from silver to a more comprehensive mining history would enrich our understanding of connections from a global perspective while simultaneously excavating different patterns of mining-led growth in Latin America.

Although extractive activities and trade have been previously studied in order to understand Latin America’s intimate links to the emerging capitalist world economy, other existing works also examine the role of knowledge production in this process. Some have argued that the growing influence of physiocracy and political economy in 18th century Spanish America fostered the pursuit of knowledge production for the purpose of wealth creation among imperial bureaucrats. However, María José Afanador qualifies this longstanding view by showing how colonial officials produced local discourses of political economy and negotiated imperial policies based on geographical realities and practices of local knowledge production. As she shows, through analyzing chorographic texts, the search for colonial wealth production and territorial integration did not only emerge as a result of the influence of intellectual treatises produced in Europe but also in the wake of writings generated due to specific colonial contexts in outposts of Spanish America. Studying the local knowledge that shaped territoriality and capital accumulation is, as she argues, necessary to understand the variegated histories of global capitalism.

In the 19th-century, Marx and Engels saw the Gold Rush as an important contribution to the dynamics of industrial capitalism. Analiese Richard and Arturo Giráldez argue that its conditions of possibility were laid out between the 16th and 18th centuries through complex geopolitical and ecological connections, originating in the sea otter and other marine mammals trade. As they point out, the European merchants’ quest to supply the lucrative Chinese luxury market with furs-“soft gold”-brought them into contact with indigenous peoples in America who, in turn, took part in intercontinental market exchange. This trade also brought foreign agents to the Pacific coast and motivated Spanish imperial authorities towards their own colonization projects in California. The prior existence of these global markets, centered on silver and “soft gold,” as they contend, was central to the creation of a Pacific Ocean economy, and sheds light on the subsequent California gold rush, crucial to the dynamics of industrial capitalism from the mid-19th century onwards.

In the past 30 years, the subject of capitalist development in pre-20th century China has received increased interest and remarkable attention.70 The article by Kaixiang Peng and Liangping Shen in this special issue scrutinizes the institutional innovations in credit markets in Ming and Qing China between the 16th and 19th centuries. This is a topic that has been generally neglected in the existing scholarship. The authors present new data on credit markets and interest rates and argue that the mechanisms of capital markets were not dissimilar to those in Europe. Late imperial China’s disadvantages in finance vis-à-vis Europe, as they suggest, were not a consequence of underdeveloped financial markets as such but rather a result of Chinese financial institutions’ specific organizational obstacles and their peculiar relationship with the state.

Within the historiography of pre-colonial and early colonial capitalism in India, the history of Gujarat is perhaps the most dynamic field of investigation.71 Ghulam Nadri contributes to this rising body of literature by analyzing the links between production, demand structures, merchant capital, commerce, credit and power relations in pre-colonial Gujarat. In particular, he examines the features and causes of the increasing volume of 17th- and 18th-century textile production in Gujarat and its growing internal and external markets across Afro-Eurasia and the Americas. He argues that Surat/Gujarat was somewhat different from other production centers due to the inability of merchant capital to control production relations in the textile industry as it did in Bengal during the early British colonial rule.

The past decade has not only witnessed a renewed interest in the problem of capitalism in the history of various regions in Asia but also in pre-colonial and early colonial Africa.72 The analysis of the nature and dynamics of merchant capitalism in the Western Indian Ocean world is another such expanding field of enquiry.73 In his study, Richard Allen examines merchant capital’s role in large-scale transoceanic labor migration in this part of the globe. More specifically, he demonstrates that the late 18th- and early 19th-century Mascarene slave trade and early indentured labor migration to Mauritius was shaped not only by metropolitan European merchant capital but also by colonial and Indian mercantile interests. In so doing, he highlights the need to appreciate the complexity of commercial relations in the Indian Ocean, including the important role that Arab/Swahili, Chinese, and Indian mercantile interests played in shaping local and regional socio-economic and political life in an age of intensifying European colonialism and imperialism.

The relationship between slavery and capitalism has been a burgeoning field of study ever since Eric Williams published his classic Capitalism and Slavery (1944).74 Tâmis Parron’s contribution to the debate is a plea for restoring “the historicity of capital and slavery” by way of periodizing different stages of slave-based production in the Americas between 1780 and 1860. He posits that 19th-century capitalism can only be understood in its global totality and argues that the relationship between slavery and capitalism was neither constituted by a “non-dialectical duality” nor by a “non-dialectical identity.” Instead, as he suggests, it has to be conceived of in its non-binary dialectical totality.

The last contribution is an interview that Juan Vicente Iborra Mallent conducted with Jairus Banaji for this special issue. It is the first available interview in Spanish that discusses his longstanding contributions to history and theory, especially concerning the problem of capitalism. Although a Marxist himself, Banaji criticizes orthodox Marxist approaches, historical theorizations and models of periodization. He advocates a broader spatio-temporal conception of capitalism, suggesting to incorporate developments that have often been considered outside of the circuits of capital. These include money and credit relations in classical antiquity, socio-economic developments in the Islamic world between the 8th and 15th centuries and unfree forms of labor relations. His recently published A Brief History of Commercial Capitalism (2020) examines the longue durée history of mercantile capitalism and has been widely received.75

As we have tried to show in this introduction, writings from and about the “Global South” have been central to discussions on the history of global capitalism(s), at least since the first decades of the 20th century, and continue to be relevant to this day. The contributions to this volume further deepen our understanding of a number of pre- and early industrial political economies in the “Global South.” The history of mercantile capital, as several contributors make plain, has wider spatio-temporal, ecological and intellectual dimensions than has previously been assumed in the existing literature (see, e.g., Bulliet, Torres, Afanador, Richard and Giráldez, Banaji in this volume). Furthermore, some of the authors of this special issue advance our knowledge about the expansion and limits of 16th to 19th century commercial, finance and agro-industrial capital in China, the Indian Ocean world and slave plantations in the Americas respectively (see, e.g., Peng and Shen, Nadri, Allen, Parron in this volume). Indeed, all contributions broaden our information about the relations, processes, structures, conjunctures and agents-especially non-Western players-in the development and rise of global capitalism(s).

In summary, it may be argued that in a variety of world regions, different forms of capitalisms evolved prior to the 19th century-the development of which was uneven and intermittent. Since the 16th century, these diverse types of capitalisms expanded gradually. From the second half of the 18th century, they began to merge into a singular Western-dominated capitalist world economy with distinct spatio-temporal specificities and manifestations-a process that was increasingly materialized from the mid-19th century on. Notwithstanding the continuity and recurrence of widespread pre- and non-capitalist features, the lopsided, hybrid and plural capitalisms of the polycentric, pre-industrial world transitioned and were combined into connected but asymmetrical varieties of a dominant, singular capitalist world order in the course of the 19th and 20th centuries.

Bibliography

Acemoglu, Daron and James A. Robinson. Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity and Poverty. London: Crown Publishing Group, 2012. [ Links ]

Adelman, Jeremy. Republic of Capital: Buenos Aires and the Legal Transformation of the Atlantic World. Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1999. [ Links ]

Alatas, Syed Farid. “Academic Dependency and the Global Division of Labour in the Social Sciences,” Current Sociology 51, n.º 6 (2003): 599-613, doi https://doi.org/10.1177/00113921030516003Links ]

Allen, Robert C. The British Industrial Revolution in Global Perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2009. [ Links ]

Andrade, Tonio. The Gunpowder Age: China, Military Innovation, and the Rise of the West in World History. New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 2016. [ Links ]

Anievas, Alexander and Kerem Nişancioğlu. How the West Came to Rule: The Geopolitical Origins of Capitalism. London: Pluto Press, 2015. [ Links ]

Aoki, Hideo. “Marxism and the Debate on the Transition to Capitalism in Prewar Japan,” Critical Sociology 47, n.º 1 (2021): 17-36, doi https://doi.org/10.1177/0896920520914074Links ]

Arguedas, Alcides. Raza de Bronce. La Paz: González y Medina, 1919. [ Links ]

Arrighi, Giovanni. Adam Smith in Beijing: Lineages of the Twenty-first Century. London: Verso, 2007. [ Links ]

Ashworth, William J. The Industrial Revolution: The State, Knowledge and Global Trade. London: Bloomsbury Publishing, 2017. [ Links ]

Assadourian, Carlos Sempat. “Modos de producción, capitalismo y subdesarrollo en América Latina,” in Modos de producción en América Latina, edited by Carlos S. Assadourian, Ciro Cardoso, Horacio Ciafardini, Juan Carlos Garavaglia and Ernesto Laclau. Buenos Aires: Siglo XXI, 1973, 47-82. [ Links ]

Bagú, Sergio. Economía de la sociedad colonial. Ensayo de Historia comparada de América Latina. Buenos Aires: El Ateneo, 1949. [ Links ]

Balázs, Étienne. “The Birth of Capitalism in China,” JESHO 3, n.º 2 (1960): 196-216, doi https://doi.org/10.2307/3596296Links ]

Banaji, Jairus. “Islam, the Mediterranean and the Rise of Capitalism,” Historical Materialism 15, n.º 1 (2007): 47-74, doi doi.org/10.1163/156920607x171591 [ Links ]

Banaji, Jairus. A Brief History of Commercial Capitalism. Chicago: Haymarket Books 2020. [ Links ]

Bazant, Jan. “Feudalismo y capitalismo en la historia de México,” El Trimestre económico 17, n.º 65 (1950): 81-98. [ Links ]

Bazant, Jan. “Una hipótesis sobre el origen del capitalismo,” El Trimestre económico 22, n.º 86 (1955): 234-40. [ Links ]

Beckert, Sven. Empire of Cotton. A Global History. New York: Knopf Doubleday Publishing Group, 2014. [ Links ]

Bellamy Foster, John and Brett Clark. The Robbery of Nature: Capitalism and the Ecological Rift. New York: Monthly Review Press, 2020. [ Links ]

Bigelow, Alison and Thomas Miller Klubock. “Introduction to Latin American Studies and the Humanities: Past, Present, Future,” Latin American Research Review 53 , n.º 3 (2018): 573-580, doi https://doi.org/10.25222/larr.521Links ]

Bihr, Alain. Le premier âge du capitalisme (1415-1763): L’expansion européenne, 3 Vols. Lausanne: Syllepse, 2018. [ Links ]

Bishara, Fahad and Hollian Wint. “Into the bazaar: Indian Ocean vernaculars in the age of global capitalism,” Journal of Global History 16, n.º 1 (2021): 44-64, doi https://doi.org/10.1017/S174002282000011XLinks ]

Blackburn, Robin. The Making of New World Slavery: From the Baroque to the Modern, 1492-1800. London: Verso , 1997. [ Links ]

Bogues, Anthony. “How Much Is Your African Slave Worth?,” differences 31, n.º 3 (2020): 156-168, doi 10.1215/10407391-8744567 [ Links ]

Bondioli, Lorenzo M., Paolo Tedesco and Michele Campopiano (eds.), Commercial Capitalism and Global History, Storica xxviii, n.º 83-84 (2022-23). [ Links ]

Bosma, Ulbe. The World of Sugar. How the Sweet Stuff Transformed Our Politics, Health, and Environment Over 2,000 Years. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2023. [ Links ]

Breckenridge, Keith. “What happened to the theory of African capitalism?,” Economy and Society 50, n.º 1 (2021): 9-35, doi https://doi.org/doi.org/10.1080/03085147.2021.1841928Links ]

Brenner, Robert. “Agrarian Class Structure and Economic Development in Pre-industrial Europe,” in The Brenner Debate: Agrarian Class Structure and Economic Development in Pre-Industrial Europe, edited by Trevor Henry Aston and Charles H. E. Philpin. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press , 1985, 10-63. [ Links ]

Brentano, Lujo. Die Anfänge des modernen Kapitalismus: Festrede gehalten in der öffentlichen Sitzung der K. Akademie der Wissenschaften am 15. März 1913. Munich: Verlag der K. B. Akademie der Wissenschaften, 1916. [ Links ]

Brook, Timothy. “Capitalism and the writing of modern history in China,” in China and Historical Capitalism: Genealogies of Sinological Knowledge, edited by Timothy Brook and Gregory Blue. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press , 1999, 110-157. [ Links ]

Brozgal, Lia Nicole. Against Autobiography: Albert Memmi and the Production of Theory. Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press, 2013. [ Links ]

Burnard, Trevor and John Garrigus. The Plantation Machine: Atlantic Capitalism in French Saint-Domingue and British Jamaica. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press, 2016. [ Links ]

Burnard, Trevor and Giorgio Riello. “Slavery and the new history of capitalism,” The Journal of Global History 15, n.º 2 (2020): 225-244, doi https://doi.org/10.1017/S1740022820000029Links ]

Candido, Mariana P. “Capitalism and Africa: Revisiting Way of Death Thirty-Five Years after its Publication,” American Historical Review 127, n.º 3 (2022): 1439-1448, doi https://doi.org/10.1093/ahr/rhac266Links ]

Cardoso, Fernando Henrique and Enzo Faletto. Dependencia y desarrollo en América Latina. Ensayo de interpretación sociológica. Lima: Instituto de Estudios Peruanos, 1967. [ Links ]

Casson, Catherine and Philipp Robinson Rössner (eds.). Evolutions of Capitalism: Historical Perspectives, 1200-2000. Bristol: Bristol University Press, 2022. [ Links ]

Castro, Santiago and Ramón Grosfoguel (eds.), El giro decolonial: reflexiones para una diversidad epistémica más allá del capitalismo global. Bogotá: Siglo del Hombre, 2007. [ Links ]

Chandra, Satish. “Some Aspects of the Growth of a Money Economy in India during the Seventeenth Century” [1962] , The Indian Economic and Social History Review 3, n.º 4 (1966): 321-31. [ Links ]

Chapin, Edwin Hubbell. Humanity in the City. New York: De Witt and Davenport, 1854. [ Links ]

Cheney, Paul. Cul de Sac: Patrimony, Capitalism, and Slavery in French Saint-Domingue. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2017. [ Links ]

Chiu, Pengsheng. “Commercialization in Late Ming China: Seeds of Capitalism?,” Oxford Research Encyclopedia: Asian History, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2022), Online: doi https://doi.org/10.1093/acrefore/9780190277727.013.619Links ]

Çızakça, Murat. Islamic Capitalism and Finance: Origins, Evolution and the Future. Cheltenham, uk: Edward Elgar, 2011. [ Links ]

Clark, Gregory. A Farewell to Alms: A Brief Economic History of the World. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2007. [ Links ]

Clarke, Marlea. “Global South: What does it mean and why use the term?,” in Global South Political Commentaries (Blog), University of Victoria, 2018. https://onlineacademiccommunity.uvic.ca/globalsouthpolitics/2018/08/08/global-south-what-does-it-mean-and-why-use-the-term/Links ]

Clegg, John. “A Theory of Capitalist Slavery,” Journal of Historical Sociology 33, n.º 1 (2020): 74-98. [ Links ]

Conermann, Stephan and Michael Zeuske (eds.). The Slavery / Capitalism Debate Global. From “Capitalism and Slavery” to Slavery as Capitalism, Comparativ 30, n.º 5/6 (2020). [ Links ]

Conroy, William. “Race, Capitalism, and the Necessity/Contingency Debate,” Theory, Culture & Society (2022): 1-19, doi https://doi.org/doi.org/10.1177/02632764221140780Links ]

Cooper, Frederick. Africa in the World: Capitalism, Empire, Nation-State. Cambridge, Harvard University Press, 2014. [ Links ]

Coronil, Fernando. “Más allá del occidentalismo: hacia categorías geohistóricas no-imperiales,” in Teorías sin disciplinas. Latinoamericanismo, poscolonialidad y globalización en debate, edited by Santiago Castro Gómez y Eduardo Mendieta. México: Miguel Ángel Porrúa/Universidad de San Francisco, 1998, 121-146. [ Links ]

Dados, Nour and Connell, Raewyn. “The Global South,” Contexts 11, n.º 1 (2012): 12-13, doi https://doi.org/10.1177/1536504212436479Links ]

Daly, Jonathan. How Europe Made the Modern World: Creating the Great Divergence. London: Bloomsbury, 2020. [ Links ]

Deng, Kent. The Chinese Premodern Economy: Structural Equilibrium and Capitalist Sterility. London: Routledge Press, 1999. [ Links ]

Deng, Kent. “One-Off Capitalism in Song China, 960-1279 AD,” in Capitalisms: Towards a Global History, edited by Kaveh Yazdani and Dilip Menon. Delhi: Oxford Unversity Press, 2020, 227-250. [ Links ]

Doren, Alfred. Entwicklung und Organisation der Florentiner Zünfte im 13. und 14. Jahrhundert. Leipzig: Duncker und Humblot, 1897. [ Links ]

Diamond, Jared. Guns, Germs and Steel: The Fates of Human Societies. New York: W.W. Norton, 1997. [ Links ]

Dick, Robert. Marriage and Population; their Natural Laws. London: Dyer, 1858. [ Links ]

Dirlik, Arif. “Chinese Historians and the Marxist Concept of Capitalism: A Critical Examination,” Modern China 8, n.º 1 (1982): 105-32. [ Links ]

Dixin, Xu and Wu Chengming. Chinese Capitalism, 1522-1840. New York: St. Martin’s Press, 2000. [ Links ]

Du Bois, William Edward Burghardt. Black Folk Then and Now. An Essay in the History and Sociology of the Negro Race [1939]. New York: Oxford University Press, 2007. [ Links ]

Duchesne, Ricardo. The Uniqueness of Western Civilization. Leiden: Brill, 2011. [ Links ]

Dussel, Enrique. El último Marx y la liberación latinoamericana. Un comentario a la tercera y a la cuarta redacción de El Capital. México DF, Madrid, Bogotá: Siglo xxi, 1990. [ Links ]

Dussel, Enrique. 1492 El encubrimiento del otro: hacia el origen del mito de la modernidad [1992]. Buenos Aires: Docencia, 2012 [1992]. [ Links ]

Escobar, Arturo. Mas allá del Tercer Mundo. Globalización y diferencia. Bogotá: icanh, 2005. [ Links ]

Fajardo, Marcelo Emiliano Perelman. “Reseña de A Brief History of Commercial Capitalism,” Antagónica. Revista de investigación y crítica social, n.º 3 (2021): 147-158. [ Links ]

Fajardo, Margarita. The World That Latin America Created. The United Nations Economic Commission for Latin America in the Development Era. Boston: Harvard University Press, 2021. [ Links ]

Faure, David. China and Capitalism. A History of Business Enterprise in Modern China. Hong Kong: Hong Kong University Press, 2006. [ Links ]

Ferguson, Niall. Civilization: The West and the Rest. London: Penguin, 2011. [ Links ]

Feuerwerker, Albert. “Review: From ‘Feudalism’ to ‘Capitalism’ in Recent Historical Writing from Mainland China,” The Journal of Asian Studies 18, n.º 1 (1958): 107-116, https://doi.org/10.2307/2941290Links ]

Findlay, Ronald and Kevin H. O’Rourke, Power and Plenty: Trade, War, and the World Economy in the Second Millennium. Princeton: Princeton University Press , 2009. [ Links ]

Flynn, Dennis O. “Silver, Globalization and Capitalism,” in Capitalisms: Towards a Global History, edited by Kaveh Yazdani andDilip Menon . Delhi: Oxford University Press, 2020. [ Links ]

Frank, André Gunder. Capitalism and Underdevelopment in Latin America. Historical Studies of Chile and Brazil [1967]. New York/London: Monthly Review Press, 2009. [ Links ]

Frank, André Gunder. Latin America: Underdevelopment or Revolution. New York: Monthly Review Press , 1969. [ Links ]

Frank, André Gunder. ReORIENT: Global Economy in the Asian Age. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1998. [ Links ]

Fraser, Nancy. Cannibal Capitalism. How Our System is Devouring Democracy, Care, and the Planet - and What We Can Do About It. London: Verso , 2022. [ Links ]

Gaido, Daniel y Constanza Bosch Alessio. “Primera aproximación a una interpretación materialista de la historia argentina: ‘Aportes para una historia de la cultura en Argentina’ de Germán Avé-Lallemant (1890),” Revista izquierdas, n.º15 (2013): 141-169. [ Links ]

Galor, Oded. The Journey of Humanity. The Origins of Wealth and Inequality. New York: Penguin, 2022. [ Links ]

Gates, Hill. China’s Motor: A Thousand Years of Petty Capitalism. Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1996. [ Links ]

Gerritsen, Anne. “The View from Early Modern China Capitalism and the Jingdezhen Ceramics Industry,” in Capitalisms: Towards a Global History, edited by Kaveh Yazdani andDilip Menon . Delhi: Oxford Unversity Press , 2020, 306-326. [ Links ]

Gerstenberger, Heide. Market and Violence: The Functioning of Capitalism in History [2017]. Leiden/Boston: Brill, 2022. [ Links ]

Giráldez, Arturo. “Monetary Flows and Currency Management in Ming-Qing,” Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Asian History (2022), Online: doi https://doi.org/10.1093/acrefore/9780190277727.013.625Links ]

Go, Julian. “Three Tensions in the Theory of Racial Capitalism,” Sociological Theory 39, n.º 1 (2021): 38-47, doi doi.org/10.1177/0735275120979822 [ Links ]

Gokhale, Balkrishna Govind. “Capital Accumulation in XVIIth Century Western India,” Journal of the Asiatic Society of Bombay 39-40 (1964/65): 51-60. [ Links ]

Goldstone, Jack A. Why Europe? The Rise of the West in World History, 1500- 1800. Boston: McGraw-Hill Education, 2008. [ Links ]

González Casanova, Pablo. “Sociedad plural, colonialismo interno y desarrollo,” America Latina, Revista del Centro Latinoamericano de Investigaciones en Ciencias Sociales 6, n.° 3 (1963): 15-32. [ Links ]

González Casanova, Pablo. “Internal Colonialism and National Development,” Studies in Comparative International Development 1 (1965): 27-37. [ Links ]

Goody, Jack. The East in the West. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press 1996. [ Links ]

Goody, Jack. Capitalism and Modernity: The Great Debate. Oxford: Polity Press, 2004. [ Links ]

Goody, Jack. The Eurasian Miracle. Cambridge: John Wiley & Sons, 2010. [ Links ]

Gopal, Surendra. Commerce and Crafts in Gujarat, 16th and 17th Centuries: A Study in the Impact of European Expansion on Precapitalist Economy. New Delhi: People’s Publishing House 1975. [ Links ]

Gran, Peter. Islamic Roots of Capitalism: Egypt, 1760-1840. Austin: University of Texas Press, 1979. [ Links ]

Green, Toby. “Africa and Capitalism: Repairing a History of Omission,” Capitalism: A Journal of History and Economics 3, n.º 2 (2022): 301-332, doi:10.1353/cap.2022.0012 [ Links ]

Grinin, Leonid E. and Andrey V. Korotayev. Great Divergence and Great Convergence: A Global Perspective. Cham: Springer, 2015. [ Links ]

Grovogu, Siba. “A Revolution Nonetheless: The Global South in International Relations,” The Global South 5, n.º 1 (2011): 175-190, doi https://doi.org/10.1353/gbs.2011.0010Links ]

Grüner, Eduardo. The Haitian Revolution: Capitalism, Slavery, and Counter-Modernity [2017]. Cambridge: Polity, 2020. [ Links ]

Hall, Catherine. “Racial Capitalism: What’s in a Name?,” History Workshop Journal 94 (2022): 1-17, doi https://doi.org/10.1093/hwj/dbac022Links ]

Hall, Peter A., and David Soskice (eds.). Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Oxford: Oxford University Press , 2001. [ Links ]

Hamade, Houssam and Christoph Sorg. “Rassismus und Kapitalismus,” in Rassismusforschung I. Theoretische und interdisziplinäre Perspektiven, edited by Nationaler Diskriminierungs- und Rassismusmonitor (Bielefeld: transcript, 2023): 251-91. [ Links ]

Hanna, Nelly. Artisan entrepreneurs in Cairo and early-modern capitalism (1600-1800). Syracuse: Syracuse University Press, 2011. [ Links ]

Hardiman, David. “Penetration of merchant capital in pre-colonial Gujarat,” in Capitalist Development: Critical Essays, edited by Ghanshyam Shah. Bombay: Popular Prakashan 1990, 29-44. [ Links ]

Harvey, David. A Companion to Marx’s Capital (Vol. 1). London: Verso , 2010. [ Links ]

Haynes, Douglas E. “Vernacular Capitalism, Advertising, and the Bazaar in Early Twentieth-Century Western India,” in Rethinking Markets in Modern India Embedded Exchange and Contested Jurisdiction, edited by Ajay Gandhi, Barbara Harriss-White, Douglas E. Haynes and Sebastian Schwecke (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press , 2020), 116-146. [ Links ]

Heck, Gene W. Charlemagne. Muhammad and the Arab Roots of Capitalism. Berlin: Walter de Gruyter, 2006. [ Links ]

Heller, Henry. The Birth of Capitalism. London: Pluto Press , 2011. [ Links ]

Heller, Henry. A Marxist History of Capitalism. New York: Routledge, 2019. [ Links ]

Serrano Hernández, Sergio T. “Producing Gold and Silver to Globalize the Economy during the Early Modern Era: San Luis Potosi and the Pacific Trade with Asia,” Asian Review of World Histories 10, n.º 1 (2022), 58-96, doi https://doi.org/10.1163/22879811-12340104Links ]

Hirschman, Albert. The Strategy of Economic Development. New Haven, Conn: Yale Univ. Press, 1958. [ Links ]

Ho, Ping-ti. “The Salt Merchants of Yang-Chou: A Study of Commercial Capitalism in Eighteenth-Century China,” Harvard Journal of Asiatic Studies 17, n.º 1/2 (1954): 130-168, doi https://doi.org/10.2307/2718130Links ]

Hobson, John M. The Eastern Origins of Western Civilisation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press , 2004. [ Links ]

Hobson, John M. Multicultural Origins of the Global Economy: Beyond the Western-Centric Frontier. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press , 2021. [ Links ]

Hoffman, Philip T. Why Did Europe Conquer the World? New Jersey: Princeton University Press , 2015. [ Links ]

Hofmeyr, Isabel. “Against the Global South,” in The Global South and Literature, edited by Russell West-Pavlov. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press , 2018. [ Links ]

Hoston, Germaine. Marxism and the Crisis of Development in Prewar Japan. Princeton: Princeton University Press , 1990. [ Links ]

Hung, Ho-Fung. The China Boom: Why China Will Not Rule the World. New York: Columbia University Press, 2015. [ Links ]

Ibrahim, Mahmood. Merchant Capital and Islam. Austin: University of Texas Press , 1990. [ Links ]

Iliffe, John. The Emergence of African Capitalism. London: Macmillan, 1983. [ Links ]

Ince, Onur Ulas. “Deprovincializing racial capitalism: John Crawfurd and settler colonialism in India,” American Political Science Review 116, n.º 1 (2022): 144-160, doi https://doi.org/10.1017/s0003055421000939Links ]

Inikori, Joseph E. Africans and the Industrial Revolution in England: A Study in International Trade and Economic Development. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press , 2002. [ Links ]

Inikori, Joseph E. “Euro-African Trade Relations and Socioeconomic Development in West Africa, 1450-1900,” Oxford Research Encyclopedia of African History. Oxford: Oxford University Press , 2019, doi https://doi.org/10.1093/acrefore/9780190277734.013.276Links ]

Inikori, Joseph E. “Atlantic Slavery and the Rise of the Capitalist Global Economy,” Current Anthropology 61, n.º 22 (2020): 159-171, doi https://doi.org/10.1086/710707Links ]

Jha, Shiva Chandra. Studies in the Development of Capitalism in India. Calcutta: Firma K. L. Mukhopadhyay, 1963. [ Links ]

Jakes, Aaron G. Egypt’s Occupation: Colonial Economism and the Crises of Capitalism. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 2020. [ Links ]

James, Cyril Lionel Robert. The Black Jacobins: Toussaint L’Ouverture and the San Domingo Revolution [1938]. New York: Vintage Books, 1989. [ Links ]

Jerven, Morten. “The Emergence of Capitalism in Africa,” in The Cambridge History of Capitalism , Vol. 1, edited by Larry Neal. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press , 2015, 431-454. [ Links ]

Karl, Rebecca E. The Magic of Concepts History and the Economic in Twentieth-Century China. Durham: Duke University Press, 2017. [ Links ]

Kautsky, Karl. Die Agrarfrage. Eine Uebersicht über die Tendenzen der modernen Landwirtschaft und die Agrarpolitik der Sozialdemokratie [1899]. Stuttgart: J.H.W. Dietz, 1902. [ Links ]

Kilinçoğlu, Deniz T. Economics and Capitalism in the Ottoman Empire. Abingdon: Routledge 2015. [ Links ]

Kocka, Jürgen and Marcel van der Linden (eds.). Capitalism: The Reemergence of a Historical Concept. London: Bloomsbury , 2016. [ Links ]

Kocka, Jürgen . Capitalism. A Short History. Princeton: Princeton University Press , 2016. [ Links ]

Koehler, Benedikt. Early Islam and the Birth of Capitalism. Lanham: Lexington Books, 2014. [ Links ]

Kuroda, Akinobu. A Global History of Money. Abingdon: Routledge , 2020. [ Links ]

Labib, Subhi Y. “Capitalism in Medieval Islam,” Journal of Economic History 29, n.º 1 (1969): 79-96, doi https://doi.org/10.1017/S0022050700097837Links ]

Nemser, Daniel and John D. Blanco (eds.). Capitalism-Catholicism-Colonialism, Journal for Early Modern Cultural Studies 19, n.º 2 (2019). [ Links ]

Nesbitt, Nick. The Price of Slavery Capitalism and Revolution in the Caribbean. Charlottesville: University of Virginia Press, 2022. [ Links ]

Kourí, Emilio. A Pueblo Divided: Business, Property and Community in Papantla. Mexico. Stanford: Stanford University Press , 2004. [ Links ]

Koyama, Mark and Jared Rubin. How the World Became Rich: The Historical Origins of Economic Growth. Cambridge: Polity Press, 2022. [ Links ]

Kuran, Timur. The Long Divergence: How Islamic Law Held Back the Middle East. New Jersey: Princeton University Press , 2010. [ Links ]

Kusch, Rodolfo. La seducción de la barbarie: análisis herético de un continente mestizo. Buenos Aires: Raigal, 1953. [ Links ]

Laclau, Ernesto. “Feudalism and Capitalism in Latin America,” New Left Review 67 (1971): 19-38. [ Links ]

Lafrance, Xavier and Charles Post (eds.). Case Studies in the Origins of Capitalism. Cham: Springer , 2019. [ Links ]

Landes, David S. The Wealth and Poverty of Nations: Why Some are so Rich and Some so Poor. London: Little, Brown and Co., 1998 [ Links ]

Lane, Kris. Potosí: The Silver City That Changed the World. University of California Press, 2019. [ Links ]

Laporte, Albert. Le Problème Monétaire dans nos vieilles Colonies. Papier-Monnaie et Bons de Caisse. Paris: A. Challamel, 1908. [ Links ]

Lenin, Vladimir I. “New Data on the Laws Governing the Development of Capitalism in Agriculture. Part One: Capitalism and Agriculture in the United States of America” [1915] (1917), in Collected Works, Vol. 22. Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1964. [ Links ]

Levander, Caroline and Walter Mignolo. “Introduction,” The Global South 5, n.º 1 (2011): 1-11. [ Links ]

Lewis, David Levering. W. E. B. Du Bois, 1919-1963: The Fight for Equality and the American Century. New York: Henry Holt, 2000. [ Links ]

Lieberman, Victor. Strange Parallels: Southeast Asia in Global Context, c.800-1830, Vol. 2. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press , 2009. [ Links ]

Liu, Andrew B. Tea War: A History of Capitalism in China and India. New Haven: Yale University Press, 2020. [ Links ]

Lopes Góes, Weber and Deivison M. Faustino. “Capitalism and Racism in the Longue Durée: An Analysis of Their Reflexive Determinations,” Agrarian South: Journal of Political Economy 11, n.º 1 (2022): 62-84, doi https://doi.org/10.1177/22779760211073683Links ]

López, Alfred. “Introduction: The (Post) Global South.” The Global South 1, n.º 1 (2007): 1-11. [ Links ]

Lopez, Robert S. The Commercial Revolution of the Middle Ages, 950-1350. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, Inc., 1971. [ Links ]

Machado, Pedro. Ocean of Trade: South Asian Merchants, Africa and the Indian Ocean, c. 1750-1850. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press , 2014. [ Links ]

Mahler, Anne Garland. “The Global South in the Belly of the Beast. Viewing African American Civil Rights through a Tricontinental Lens,” Latin American Research Review, 50, n.º 1 (2015): 95-116, doi https://doi.org/10.1353/lar.2015.0007Links ]

Magallanes, Rodolfo. “On the Global South,” in Concepts of the Global South - Voices from around the world, edited by Andrea Hollington, Tijo Salverda, Tobias Schwarz and Oliver Tappe. Cologne: Global South Studies Center, University of Cologne, 2015, 95-116. [ Links ]

Marchant, Alexander. “Feudal and capitalistic elements in the Portuguese settlement of Brazil,” Hispanic American Historical Review 22, n.º 3 (1942): 493-512, doi https://doi.org/10.2307/2506836Links ]

Mariátegui, José Carlos. Siete ensayos de interpretación de la realidad peruana [1928]. Caracas: Biblioteca de Ayacuho, 2007. [ Links ]

Marini, Ruy Mauro. Dialéctica de la dependencia. México: Ediciones Era, 1973. [ Links ]

Marini, Ruy Mauro. Subdesarrollo y revolución. México: Siglo xxi Editores, 1974. [ Links ]

Marks, Robert. “Commercialization without Capitalism: Processes of Environmental Change in South China, 1550-1850,” Environmental History 1, n.º 1 (1996): 56-82. [ Links ]

Marks, Robert. The Origins of the Modern World: Fate and Fortune in the Rise of the West. Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, 2007. [ Links ]

Marks, Steven G. The Information Nexus: Global Capitalism from the Renaissance to the Present. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press , 2016. [ Links ]

Marques, Leonardo. “Slavery and Capitalism,” in The SAGE Handbook of Marxism, edited by Beverley Skeggs, Sara R. Farris, Alberto Toscano and Svenja Bromberg. London: sage, 2022, 248-267. [ Links ]

Martin, Gaston. L‘ère des négriers (1714-1774): Nantes au xviiie siècle [1931]. Paris: Karthala, 1993. [ Links ]

Martin, Gaston. Capital et travail à Nantes au cours du xviiie siècle. Paris: M. Rivière, 1931. [ Links ]

Marx, Karl. Grundrisse. Foundations of the Critique of Political Economy (Rough Draft) [1939]. London: Penguin , 1993. [ Links ]

Marx, Karl. Capital: A Critique of Political Economy [1867], Vol. 1. London: Penguin , 1982. [ Links ]

Marx, Karl. Capital: A Critique of Political Economy [1885], Vol. 2. London: Penguin , 1992. [ Links ]

Marx, Karl. Capital: A Critique of Political Economy [1894], Vol. 3. London: Penguin , 1993. [ Links ]

Marquardt, Jens. “Worlds apart? The Global South and the Anthropocene,” in The Anthropocene Debate and Political Science, edited by Thomas Hickmann, Lena Partzsch, Philipp Pattberg, Sabine Weiland. New York: Routledge , 2019, 200-218. [ Links ]

Mathew, John. Margins of the market: Trafficking and capitalism across the Arabian Sea. Berkeley: University of California Press , 2016. [ Links ]

McCloskey, Deirdre N. Bourgeois Equality: How Ideas, Not Capital or Institutions, Enriched the World. Chicago: University of Chicago Press , 2016. [ Links ]

McNally, David. Blood and Money. War, Slavery, Finance, and Empire. Chicago, Haymarket Books, 2020. [ Links ]

Maddison, Angus. Contours of the World Economy, I-2030 AD: Essays in Macro-Economic History. Oxford: Oxford University Press , 2007. [ Links ]

Mielants, Eric. The Origins of Capitalism and the “Rise of the West.” Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 2007. [ Links ]

Mignolo, Walter. The Darker Side of the Renaissance: Literacy, Territoriality, Colonization. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1995. [ Links ]

Mignolo, Walter. The Idea of Latin America. Maden/Oxford/Victoria: Blackwell, 2005. [ Links ]

Miller, Joseph C. Way of death: merchant capitalism and the Angolan slave trade, 1730-1830. Madison, University of Wisconsin Press, 1988. [ Links ]

Mariátegui, Josè Carlos. Siete ensayos de interpretación de la realidad peruana. Caracas: Fundación Biblioteca Ayacucho, 2007. [ Links ]

Miranda, José. “La función económica del encomendero en los orígenes del régimen colonial de Nueva España 1525-1531,” Anales del Instituto Nacional de Antropología e Historia 2 (1941-46): 421-62. https://revistas.inah.gob.mx/index.php/anales/article/view/7028. [ Links ]

Mohajer, Nasser andKaveh Yazdani . “Reading Marx in the Divergence Debate,” in What’s Left of Marxism: Historiography and the Possibilities of Thinking with Marxian Themes and Concepts, edited by Benjamin Zachariah, Lutz Raphael & Brigitta Bernet. Berlin/Boston: De Gruyter Oldenbourg, 2020: 173-240, doi https://doi.org/10.1515/9783110677744-010Links ]

Mokyr, Joel. A Culture of Growth: The Origins of the Modern Economy. New Jersey: Princeton University Press , 2016. [ Links ]

Moore, Jason. “‘This lofty mountain of silver could conquer the whole world’: Potosí and the political ecology of underdevelopment, 1545-1800,” The Journal of Philosophical Economics 4, n.º 1, (2010), 58-103, doi https://doi.org/10.46298/jpe.10605Links ]

Moore, Jason W. Capitalism in the Web of Life: Ecology and the Accumulation of Capital. London: Verso Press, 2015. [ Links ]

Moore, Jason W. Capitalism in the Web of Life and Anthropocene or Capitalocene? Nature, History, and the Crisis of Capitalism. Oakland: PM Press, 2016. [ Links ]

More, Anna. “The Early Portuguese Slave Ship and the Infrastructure of Racial Capitalism,” Social Text 40, n.º 4 (2022): 17-41, doi https://doi.org/10.1215/01642472-10013290Links ]

Moreland, William H. India at the Death of Akbar. An Economic Study. London: Macmillan , 1920. [ Links ]

Morgan, Jennifer L. Reckoning with Slavery. Gender, Kinship, and Capitalism in the Early Black Atlantic. Durham, Duke University Press, 2021. [ Links ]

Morris, Ian. Why the West Rules Rules-for Now: The Patterns of History and what they Reveal about the Future. London: Profile Books, 2010. [ Links ]

Murray, Patrick. The Mismeasure of Wealth: Essays on Marx and Social Form. Leiden: Brill , 2016. [ Links ]

Needham, Joseph. “On Science and Social Change,” Science & Society 10, n.º 3 (1946): 225-251. https://www.jstor.org/stable/40399766Links ]

Neil, Larry and Jeffrey G. Williamson (eds.). The Cambridge History of Capitalism, 2 Vols. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press , 2014. [ Links ]

Oglesby, Carl. “Vietnamism has failed...The revolution can only be mauled, not defeated,” Commonweal 90 (1969). [ Links ]

Olías, Joaquín Martín de. “Movimiento Obrero en Europa y America Durante el Siglo xix,” Revista Europea 2 (9.8.1874): 170-79. [ Links ]

O’Sullivan, Michael. “Vernacular Capitalism and Intellectual History in a Gujarati Account of China, 1860-68,” The Journal of Asian Studies 80, n.º 2 (2021): 267-292, doi https://doi.org/10.1017/S0021911820003678Links ]

Pamuk, Şevket. “Institutional Change and Economic Development in the Middle East, 700- 1800,” in The Cambridge History of Capitalism, Vol. 1, edited by Larry Neal, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press , 2014, 193-224. [ Links ]

Parthasarathi, Prasannan. Why Europe Grew Rich and Asia Did Not: Global Economic Divergence, 1600-1850. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press , 2011. [ Links ]

Paton, Diana. “Gender History, Global History, and Atlantic Slavery. Racial Capitalism and Social Reproduction,” The American Historical Review 127, n.º 2 (2022): 726-754, doi https://doi.org/10.1093/ahr/rhac156WLinks ]

Pavlov, Vladimir Ivanovich. The Indian Capitalist Class: A Historical Study. New Delhi: People’s Publishing House , 1964. [ Links ]

Pieper, Renate, Claudia de Lozanne Jefferies and Markus Denzel (eds.). Mining, Money and Markets in the Early Modern Atlantic. Cham: Palgrave Macmillan, 2019. [ Links ]

Piketty, Thomas. Capital and Ideology. Cambridge: Harvard University Press , 2020. [ Links ]

Pirenne, Henri. “The Stages in the History of Capitalism,” American Historical Review 19, n.º 3 (1914): 494-515. [ Links ]

Pirenne, Henri. Medieval Cities: Their Origins and the Revival of Trade, trans. Frank D. Halsey. Princeton: Princeton University Press , 1925. [ Links ]

Pretel, David. “Capitalismo y esclavitud: Nuevas historias, viejos debates,” Ayer 126, n.º2 (2022): 331-345, doi https://doi.org/10.55509/ayer/886Links ]

Pétré-Grenouilleau, Olivier. L’argent de la traite. Milieu négrier, capitalisme et development: un modèle. Paris: Aubier, 1996. [ Links ]

Pomeranz, Kenneth. The Great Divergence: China, Europe and the Making of the Modern World. Princeton: Princeton University Press , 2000. [ Links ]

Prado Júnior, Caio. Formacão do Brasil contemporâneo: Colônia [1942]. Sao Paulo: Brasiliense, 1981. [ Links ]

Prashad, Vijay. The Poorer Nations: A Possible History of the Global South. London: Verso , 2012. [ Links ]

Prebisch, Raúl. El desarrollo económico de América Latina y algunos de sus principales problemas [1949]. New York: United Nations, 1950. [ Links ]

Puiggros, Rodolfo. De la Colonia a la Revolución. Buenos Aires: Partenon, 1949. [ Links ]

Quijano, Aníbal. “Coloniality of Power and Eurocentrism in Latin America.” International Sociology 15, n.º 2 (2000): 215-232, doi https://doi.org/10.1177/0268580900015002Links ]

Ralph, Michael and Maya Singhal. “Racial capitalism,” Theory and Society 48 (2019): 851-881, doi https://doi.org/10.1007/s11186-019-09367-zLinks ]

Rama, Jonas and John Hall. “Raúl Prebisch and the evolving uses of ‘centre-periphery’ in economic analysis,” Review of Evolutionary Political Economy 2 (2021): 315-332, doi https://doi.org/10.1007/s43253-021-00036-5Links ]

Rieppel, Lukas et al. (eds.). Science and Capitalism: Entangled Histories, Osiris 33 (2018). [ Links ]

Rivera Cusicanqui, Silvia. Debates postcoloniales. La Paz: Sephis, 1997. [ Links ]

Robinson, Cedric J. Black Marxism: The Making of the Black Radical Tradition [1983]. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 2000. [ Links ]

Rodinson, Maxime. Islam and Capitalism [1966]. Austin: University of Texas Press , 1978. [ Links ]

Rood, Daniel. The Reinvention of Atlantic Slavery: Technology, Labor, Race and Capitalism in the Greater Caribbean. Oxford: Oxford University Press , 2020. [ Links ]

Rosenthal, Jean-Laurent and Roy Bin Wong. Before and Beyond Divergence: The Politics of Economic Change in China and Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press , 2011. [ Links ]

Roy, Manabendra Nath. India in Transition. Geneva: J. B. Target, 1922. [ Links ]

Ruhland, Gustav. System der politischen Ökonomie, Vol. 3. Berlin: Issleib, 1903. [ Links ]

Sanial, Lucien. “Territorial Expansion,” Socialistic Co-operative Publ. Ass’n 1, n.º 2 (1899): 1-12. [ Links ]

Satia, Priya. Empire of Guns: The Violent Making of the Industrial Revolution. New York: Penguin , 2018. [ Links ]

Scheidel, Walter. Escape from Rome: The Failure of Empire and the Road to Prosperity. New Jersey: Princeton University Press , 2019. [ Links ]

Sée, Henri. Modern Capitalism: Its Origin and Evolution [1928]. Kitchener Ontario 2004. [ Links ]

Sell, Zach. Trouble of the World: Slavery and Empire in the Age of Capital. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press , 2021. [ Links ]

Sharman, Jason C. Empires of the Weak: The Real Story of European Expansion and the Creation of the New World Order. Princeton: Princeton University Press , 2019. [ Links ]

Sheikh, Samira. “Jibhabhu’s Rights to Ghee: Land control and vernacular capitalism in Gujarat, circa 1803-10,” Modern Asian Studies 51, n.º 2 (2017): 350-374, doi https://10.1017/S0026749X16000718Links ]

Shibasaki, Shinya and Kei Ehara. “What is commercial capital? Japanese contributions to Marxian market theory,” Capital & Class 46, n.º 2 (2022): 235-256, doi https://doi.org/10.1177/03098168211029005Links ]

Shovlin, John. Trading with the Enemy: Britain, France, and the 18th-Century Quest for a Peaceful World Order. New Haven: Yale University Press , 2021. [ Links ]

Sieveking, Heinrich. Die rheinischen Gemeinden Erpel und Unkel und ihre Entwickelung im 14. und 15. Jahrhundert. Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot, 1895. [ Links ]

Sombart, Werner. Der moderne Kapitalismus. Historisch-systematische Darstellung des gesamteuropäischen Wirtschaftslebens von seinen Anfängen bis zur Gegenwart [1902], Vol. 3. Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot , 1927. [ Links ]

Sorel, Georges. “Sur la Théorie Marxiste de la Valeur,” Journal des économistes revue bimensuelle de la science économique et de la statistique 46, n.º 30 (1897): 222-31. [ Links ]

Stanziani, Alessandro. Capital Terre. Une histoire longue du monde d’après (XIIe-XXIe siècle). Paris: Payot, 2021. [ Links ]

Stein, Stanley J. and Barbara Stein. The Colonial Heritage of Latin America. New York: Oxford University Press , 1970. [ Links ]

Strieder, Jacob. “Origin and Evolution of Early European Capitalism,” Journal of Economic and Business History 2, (1929): 1-19. [ Links ]

Sun, Lin, Gongle Yang, Ruiliang Liu, A. M. Pollard, Zhu Tiequan, Liu Cheng, “Global circulation of silver between Ming-Qing China and the Americas: Combining historical texts and scientific analyses,” archaeometry 63, n.º 3 (2021), 627-640, doi https://doi.org/10.1111/arcm.12617Links ]

Tandeter, Enrique. “Sobre el análisis de la dominación colonial,” Desarrollo Económico 16, n.º 61 (1976): 151-160. [ Links ]

Tarcus, Horacio (Dir.). Diccionario biográfico de la izquierda argentina. De los anarquistas a la “nueva izquierda 1870-1976. Buenos Aires: Emecé, 2007. [ Links ]

The Nineteenth Century and After, 106, n. º 630 (1929). [ Links ]

Tomich, Dale (ed.). Slavery and Historical Capitalism During the Nineteenth Century. Lanham: Lexington Books , 2017. [ Links ]

Trivellato, Francesca. “Renaissance Florence and the Origins of Capitalism: A Business History Perspective,” Business History Review 94, n. º1 (2020): 229-251. [ Links ]

Tutino, John. Making a New World: Founding Capitalism in the Bajío and Spanish North America. Durham/London: Duke University Press, 2011. [ Links ]

Tutino, John. The Mexican Heartland: How Communities Shaped Capitalism, a Nation, and World History, 1500-2000. Princeton: Princeton University Press , 2018. [ Links ]

Vahabi, Mehrdad. Destructive Coordination, Anfal and Islamic Political Capitalism. A New Reading of Contemporary Iran. Cham: Springer , 2023. [ Links ]

Van Zanden, Jan Luiten. The Long Road to the Industrial Revolution: The European Economy in a Global Perspective, 1000-1800. Leiden: Brill , 2009. [ Links ]

Vasconcelos, José. La raza cósmica [1925]. Espasa Calpe, México D.F. 1948. [ Links ]

Von Glahn, Richard. “The Changing Significance of Latin American Silver in the Chinese Economy, 16th-19th Centuries,” Revista de Historia Económica - Journal of Iberian and Latin American Economic History 38, n.º 3 (2019): 553-585, doi https://doi.org/10.1017/S0212610919000193Links ]

Varoufakis, Yanis. Technofeudalism: What Killed Capitalism (forthcoming), 2023. [ Links ]

Varoufakis, Yanis. “On Crypto & the Left, and Techno-Feudalism,” the crypto syllabus, 23.4.2022. https://the-crypto-syllabus.com/yanis-varoufakis-on-techno-feudalism/Links ]

Vries, Peer. Escaping Poverty: The Origins of Modern Economic Growth. Vienna: Vandenhoeck & Ruprecht, 2013. [ Links ]

Vries, Peer. State, Economy and the Great Divergence. Great Britain and China, 1680s to 1850s. London: Bloomsbury Publishing , 2015. [ Links ]

Walker, Gavin. The Sublime Perversion of Capital: Marxist Theory and the Politics of History in Modern Japan. Durham: Duke University Press , 2016. [ Links ]

Wallerstein, Immanuel. The Modern World-System. Vol. I: Capitalist Agriculture and the Origins of the European World-Economy in the Sixteenth Century. New York/London: Academic Press, 1974. [ Links ]

Wallerstein, Immanuel. The Modern World-System. Vol II: Mercantilism and the Consolidation of the European World-Economy, 1600-1750. New York: Academic Press, 1980. [ Links ]

Wallerstein, Immanuel. The Modern World-System. Vol III: The Second Great Expansion of the Capitalist World-Economy, 1730-1840s. San Diego: Academic Press, 1989. [ Links ]

Wallerstein, Immanuel. The Modern World-System. Vol. IV: Centrist Liberalism Triumphant, 1789-1914. Berkeley: University of California Press , 2011. [ Links ]

Walsh, Catherine, Alvaro García and Walter Mignolo (eds.). Interculturalidad, descolonización del Estado y del conocimiento. Buenos Aires: Editorial Signo, 2006. [ Links ]

Wang, Luman. Chinese Hinterland Capitalism and Shanxi Piaohao Banking, State, and Family, 1720-1910. Abingdon: Routledge , 2021. [ Links ]

Weber, Max. The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism [1920]. London: Routledge 2005. [ Links ]

Weber, Max. General Economic History [1923], trans. F. H. Knight. Glencoe: The Free Press 1927. [ Links ]

Weber, Max. Economy and Society. A New Translation [1922], edited and translated by Keith Tribe. Cambridge: Harvard University Press , 2019. [ Links ]

Weber, Max. Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft [1922], Vol. 3.2. Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr, 1925. [ Links ]

Whitley, Richard. Divergent Capitalisms: The Social Structuring and Change of Business Systems. Oxford: Oxford University Press , 1999. [ Links ]

“Who Invented the Locomotive?,” American Artisan and Patent Record: A Weekly Journal of arts, mechanics, manufactures, mining, engineering and chemistry, and repertory of patents 1, n.º 10 (July 12, 1865). [ Links ]

Williams, Eric. Capitalism and Slavery [1944]. Chapel Hill: The University of North Carolina Press, 2021. [ Links ]

Williamson, Jeffrey G. Trade and Poverty: When the Third World Fell Behind. Cambridge: Massachusetts Institute of Technology Press, 2011. [ Links ]

Wittfogel, Karl. Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft Chinas, Versuch der wissenschaftlichen Analyse einer großen asiatischen Agrargesellschaft. Leipzig: Hirschfeld, 1931. [ Links ]

Wong, Roy Bin. China Transformed. Historical Change and the Limits of European Experience. Ithaca and London: Cornell University Press, 1997. [ Links ]

Wong, Roy Bin. “China before capitalism,” in The Cambridge History of Capitalism, Vol. 1, edited by Larry Neal, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press , 2014, 125-164. [ Links ]

Wood, Ellen Meiksins. The Origins of Capitalism: A Longer View. London: Verso , 2002. [ Links ]

Yazdani, Kaveh. India, Modernity and the Great Divergence. Mysore and Gujarat (17th to 18th C.). Leiden: Brill , 2017. [ Links ]

Yazdani, Kaveh and Dilip Menon (eds.). Capitalisms: Towards a Global History. Delhi: Oxford University Press , 2020. [ Links ]

Yazdani, Kaveh . “Capitalism, Slavery and the Most Precious Colony in the World,” VSWG Vierteljahrschrift für Sozial- und Wirtschaftsgeschichte 108, n.º 4 (2021): 457-503, doi https://doi. org/10.25162/vswg-2021-0015Links ]

Yazdani, Kaveh . “Dadani,” in Changing Theory: Concepts from the Global South, edited by Dilip Menon . Routledge: New York, 2022, 181-196. [ Links ]

Yazdani, Kaveh . “The Biography of capitalism” (in preparation). [ Links ]

Yazdani, Kaveh . “Capitalism - Begriffsgeschichte and Definition of a Concept” (in preparation). [ Links ]

Yazdani, Kaveh . “Capitalism in Pre-Colonial India? Reconsidering the Hundred-Year Debate,” English Historical Review (2023). (Forthcoming). [ Links ]

Yü, Ying-shih. The Religious Ethic and Mercantile Spirit in Early Modern China. New York, Colombia University Press, 2021. [ Links ]

Zagalsky, Paula C. and Rossana Barragán (eds.). Potosí in the Global Silver Age (16th-19th Centuries). Leiden: Brill , 2023. [ Links ]

Zahedieh, Nuala. “Eric Williams and William Forbes: Copper, colonial markets and commercial capitalism,” The Economic History Review 74, n.º 3 (2021): 784-808, doi https://doi.org/10.1111/ehr.13050Links ]

*We would like to express our sincere gratitude to Nasser Mohajer, Jack Goldstone, James Torres and Fabio Sánchez Torres for their valuable comments and suggestions. We would also like to thank Santiago Muñoz Arbeláez for encouraging the realization of this special issue, as well as Leidy Paola Bolaños and the rest of Historia Crítica’s editorial team for their support, hard work and helpful suggestions.

1Time-space compression is a process that emanates from the spread of technological innovations, especially in the wake of the world-wide —though uneven— expansion of capital. It is characterized by the asymmetrical reduction of spatial distances and temporal differences as well as the emergence, growth and nexus of new interconnected markets. For the sake of capital accumulation, the asynchronous pace and volume of global production and commodity exchange are constantly being accelerated, and the turnover time of capital is shortened, thus, condensing time and shrinking space. It is generally assumed that David Harvey coined the term “time-space compression.” However, it is worth noting that this expression was already devised and spread between the mid-19th and early 20th century, similar to so many other crucial ideas, concepts and analytical categories. As early as 1854, Edwin Hubbell Chapin, a North American preacher and editor of the Christian Leader, wrote of “powerful instruments, condensing time and space.” See his Humanity in the City (New York: De Witt and Davenport, 1854), 40. In his Grundrisse (1857-1858), which was only published in 1939, Marx explained that: “Capital by its nature drives beyond every spatial barrier. Thus the creation of the physical conditions of exchange —of the means of communication and transport—the annihilation of space by time—becomes an extraordinary necessity for it.” Karl Marx, Grundrisse. Foundations of the Critique of Political Economy (Rough Draft) (London: Penguin, 1993) [1939], 524. In 1865, it was observed in an anonymous article that the expansion of the railway “conferred upon mankind the power of compressing time and space.” Who Invented the Locomotive?,” American Artisan and Patent Record: A Weekly Journal..., 1, n.º 10 (July 12, 1865), 148. Lastly, in 1929, when an airplane flew from Cranwell aerodrome to Karachi in 50 hours, and a regular mail service for passengers and freight had been established to India, the British politician Viscount Peel wrote the following words to Lord Irwin, the Viceroy or Governor-General of India: “This is the first time that it is possible for a Secretary of State to write a letter to the Viceroy with the assurance that it will reach India within a week of its dispatch, and I desire in the letter I transmit, as one of its first-fruits, to acclaim this new achievement in the compression of time and space.” Cited in The Nineteenth Century and After, 106, n.º 630 (1929), 244.

2Nancy Fraser, Cannibal Capitalism. How Our System is Devouring Democracy, Care, and the Planet - and What We Can Do About It (London: Verso, 2022), 24.

3Yanis Varoufakis, Technofeudalism: What Killed Capitalism (forthcoming). In a recent interview, Varoufakis contended: “Central bank money has replaced private profit (as the system’s main fuel and lubricant).” Moreover, “digital fiefdoms/platforms” are replacing markets and “have become the realm in which value and capital are extracted from the majority by a tiny oligarchy.” In other words, “[c]apital is getting stronger but capitalism is dying. A new system is taking over in which a new ruling class owns and runs both the state money that lubricates it (instead of profits) and the new non-market realms in which the very, very few make the many work on their behalf. Capitalist profits (in the sense of the entrepreneurial profits as understood by Adam Smith and Marx) are disappearing, while new forms of rent are accumulating in the accounts of the new techno-lords in control of both the state and the digital fiefs, in which unwaged or precarious work is performed by the masses - who begin to resemble techno-peasants.” “Yanis Varoufakis on Crypto & the Left, and Techno-Feudalism,” the crypto syllabus, 23.4.2022 available at https://the-crypto-syllabus.com/yanis-varoufakis-on-techno-feudalism/.

4For an early use of the term “Global South,” see Carl Oglesby, “Vietnamism has failed...The revolution can only be mauled, not defeated,” Commonweal 90 (1969). In 1952, the French demographer Alfred Sauvy coined the term “Third World” (tiers monde). He wrote that “this Third World, ignored, exploited and scorned like the Third Estate, also wants to make something of itself.” But, in 1989, even prior to the Fall of the Berlin Wall and the dissolution of the Soviet Union, he precociously distanced himself from the concept: “Do allow the creator of the expression ‘the Third World,’ now almost 40 years later, to repudiate the term, as it tends to make us forget the growing diversity of cases. Placing all the countries of black Africa and ‘the four dragons’ under a single term does not do us much good.” The two latter quotations have been drawn from Lia Nicole Brozgal, Against Autobiography: Albert Memmi and the Production of Theory (Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press, 2013), 121. The “center-periphery” approach was popularized by Raúl Prebisch who conceptualized and refined his understanding of this framework between the 1920s and 1940s. See Jonas Rama and John Hall, “Raúl Prebisch and the evolving uses of ‘centre-periphery’ in economic analysis,” Review of Evolutionary Political Economy 2 (2021): 315-332, doi 10.1007/s43253-021-00036-5

5Marlea Clarke, “Global South: What does it mean and why use the term?,” in University of Victoria-The Online Academic Community, Global South Political Commentaries (Blog) (February 8, 2023), https://onlineacademiccommunity.uvic.ca/globalsouthpolitics/2018/08/08/global-south-what-does-it-mean-and-why-use-the-term/

6Nour Dados and Raewyn Connell, “The Global South,” Context 11, nº. 1 (2012): 12-13, doi https://doi.org/10.1177/1536504212436479. See also Allison M. Bigelow and Thomas M. Klubock, “Introduction to Latin American Studies and the Humanities: Past, Present, Future,” Latin American Research Review 53, no. 3 (2018): 573-580, doi https://doi.org/10.25222/larr.521

7Caroline Levander and Walter Mignolo, “Introduction,” The Global South 5, n.º 1, (2011): 1-11; Syed Farid Alatas, “Academic Dependency and the Global Division of Labour in the Social Sciences,” Current Sociology 51, n.º 6 (2003): 599-613, doi 10.1177/00113921030516003

8Alfred López, “Introduction: The (Post) Global South,” The Global South 1, n.º 1 (2007): 1-11; Siba Grovogu, “A Revolution Nonetheless: The Global South in International Relations,” The Global South 5, n.º 1 (2011): 175-190, doi 10.1353/gbs.2011.0010

9Anne Garland Mahler, “The Global South in the Belly of the Beast. Viewing African American Civil Rights through a Tricontinental Lens,” Latin American Research Review 50, n.º 1 (2015): 95-116, doi:10.1353/lar.2015.0007

10 Vijay Prashad, The Poorer Nations: A Possible History of the Global South (London: Verso, 2012), 10. See also Rodolfo Magallanes, “On the Global South,” in Concepts of the Global South - Voices from around the world, edited by Andrea Hollington, Tijo Salverda, Tobias Schwarz and Oliver Tappe (Cologne: Global South Studies Center, University of Cologne, 2015), 9; Isabel Hofmeyr, “Against the Global South,” in The Global South and Literature, edited by Russell West-Pavlov (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2018).

11Australia and New Zealand, though geographically southern, are not part of the “Global South”. Meiji and post-Meiji Japan are also oftentimes excluded due to their economic strength and colonial legacy. But Mongolia, present-day Kazakhstan and parts of northern China, while at the same latitude as Europe, are part of it in this usage. Thus, despite the fact that most of the regions covered in this volume are geographically located in the south, the term has primarily socio-economic and political rather than geographical connotations.

12Max Weber, The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism (London: Routledge 2005 [1920], the first German edition was published in 1904/5); and General Economic History, trans. F. H. Knight (Glencoe: The Free Press 1927 [1923]).

13 Max Weber, Economy and Society. A New Translation, edited and translated by Keith Tribe (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2019 [1922]), 283. For Marx’s understanding of pre-colonial Asian, especially Indian, socio-economic formations, see Nasser Mohajer and Kaveh Yazdani, “Reading Marx in the Divergence Debate,” in What’s Left of Marxism: Historiography and the Possibilities of Thinking with Marxian Themes and Concepts, edited by Benjamin Zachariah, Lutz Raphael & Brigitta Bernet (Berlin/Boston: De Gruyter Oldenbourg, 2020): 173-240, doi https://doi.org/10.1515/9783110677744-010. For a qualification of Weber’s argument regarding India, see Kaveh Yazdani, “Capitalism in Pre-Colonial India? Reconsidering the Hundred-Year Debate,” English Historical Review (Forthcoming).

14However, he did not specify which regions in the “Islamic Orient” he was referring to. Gustav Ruhland, System der politischen Ökonomie, Vol. 3 (Berlin: Issleib, 1903), 97. See also pp. 14, 37, 40, 294.

15 For the Chinese “sprouts of capitalism” debate, see Arif Dirlik, “Chinese Historians and the Marxist Concept of Capitalism: A Critical Examination,” Modern China 8, n.º 1 (1982): 105-32; Timothy Brook, “Capitalism and the writing of modern history in China,” in China and Historical Capitalism: Genealogies of Sinological Knowledge, edited by Timothy Brook and Gregory Blue. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999), 110-57, 150-1. For Japanese debates from the 1920s onwards, see Germaine Hoston, Marxism and the Crisis of Development in Prewar Japan (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1990); Gavin Walker, The Sublime Perversion of Capital: Marxist Theory and the Politics of History in Modern Japan (Durham: Duke University Press, 2016); Hideo Aoki, “Marxism and the Debate on the Transition to Capitalism in Prewar Japan,” Critical Sociology 47, n.º 1 (2021): 17-36, doi, https://doi.org/10.1177/0896920520914074

16Manabendra Nath Roy, India in Transition (Geneva: J. B. Target, 1922), 98-9. The then-leading economic historian of India, William H. Moreland, argued otherwise. See his India at the Death of Akbar. An Economic Study (London: Macmillan, 1920), 51, 148, 184. See also Yazdani, “Capitalism in Pre-Colonial India?”.

17Quoted in Dirlik, “Chinese Historians,” 106. At that time, the majority of European scholars held the opposite view. For the most prominent examples, see Karl Wittfogel, Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft Chinas, Versuch der wissenschaftlichen Analyse einer großen asiatischen Agrargesellschaft (Leipzig: Hirschfeld, 1931); Joseph Needham, “On Science and Social Change,” Science & Society 10, n.º 3 (1946): 225-251.

18Karl Marx, Capital: A Critique of Political Economy, Vol. 1 (London: Penguin, 1982 [1867]), 345, 920, 915. For an assessment and discussion of Marx’s views, see Mohajer and Yazdani, “Reading Marx”; Kaveh Yazdani, “Capitalism, Slavery and the Most Precious Colony in the World,” VSWG Vierteljahrschrift für Sozial- und Wirtschaftsgeschichte 108, n.º 4 (2021): 457-503, 488, doi 10.25162/vswg-2021-0015

19Karl Kautsky, Die Agrarfrage. Eine Uebersicht über die Tendenzen der modernen Landwirtschaft und die Agrarpolitik der Sozialdemokratie (Stuttgart: J.H.W. Dietz, 1902 [1899]), 92, 135; Werner Sombart, Der moderne Kapitalismus. Historisch-systematische Darstellung des gesamteuropäischen Wirtschaftslebens von seinen Anfängen bis zur Gegenwart, Vol. 3 (Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot, 1927 [1902]), 325-9.

20Vladimir I. Lenin, “New Data on the Laws Governing the Development of Capitalism in Agriculture. Part One: Capitalism and Agriculture in the United States of America” (1917) [1915], in Collected Works, Vol. 22 (Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1964), 30, 50; Max Weber, Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft, Vol. 3.2 (Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr, 1925 [1922]), 430.

21Henri Sée, Modern Capitalism: Its Origin and Evolution, Kitchener Ontario 2004 [1928], 66-7; Gaston Martin, L’ère des négriers (1714-1774): Nantes au xviiie siècle (Paris: Karthala, 1993 [1931] ,and Capital et travail à Nantes au cours du xviiie siècle (Paris: M. Rivière, 1931).

22Quoted in David Levering Lewis, W. E. B. Du Bois, 1919-1963: The Fight for Equality and the American Century (New York: Henry Holt, 2000), 642.

23William Edward Burghardt Du Bois, Black Folk Then and Now. An Essay in the History and Sociology of the Negro Race (New York: Oxford University Press, 2007 [1939]), 99.

24Cyril Lionel Robert James, The Black Jacobins: Toussaint L’Ouverture and the San Domingo Revolution (New York: Vintage Books, 1989 [1938]); Eric Williams, Capitalism and Slavery (Chapel Hill: The University of North Carolina Press, 2021 [1944]).

25In Le Problème Monétaire dans nos vieilles Colonies. Papier-Monnaie et Bons de Caisse (Paris: A. Challamel, 1908), 48, Albert Laporte was maybe the first to use the French designation of “mode de production coloniale.” But in contrast to Latin America and India, the term did not take hold in the francophone world before the 1960s.

26Sergio Bagú,Economía de la sociedad colonial. Ensayo de Historia comparada de América Latina(Buenos Aires: El Ateneo, 1949); Jan Bazant, “Feudalismo y capitalismo en la historia de México,” El Trimestre económico 17, n.º 65 (1950): 81-98.

27Jan Bazant, “Una hipótesis sobre el origen del capitalismo,” El Trimestre económico 22, n.º 86 (1955): 234-40. Other intellectuals favoring either a dual or a capitalist vision of the colonial economy include Alexander Marchant, “Feudal and capitalistic elements in the Portuguese settlement of Brazil,” Hispanic American Historical Review 22, n.º 3 (1942): 493-512, doi doi.org/10.2307/2506836; José Miranda, “La función económica del encomendero en los orígenes del régimen colonial de Nueva España 1525-1531,” Anales del Instituto Nacional de Antropología e Historia 2 (1941-46): 421-62; Caio Prado Júnior, Formacão do Brasil contemporâneo: Colônia (Sao Paulo: Brasiliense,1981 [1942]).

28Raúl Prebisch, El desarrollo económico de América Latina y algunos de sus principales problemas (New York: United Nations, 1950 [1949]).

29André Gunder Frank, Capitalism and Underdevelopment in Latin America. Historical Studies of Chile and Brazil (New York/London: Monthly Review Press, 2009 [1967]), 28.

30Stanley J. Stein and Barbara Stein, The Colonial Heritage of Latin America (New York: Oxford University Press, 1970); Carlos Sempat Assadourian, “Modos de producción, capitalismo y subdesarrollo en América Latina,” in Assadourian et al. Modos de producción en América Latina (Buenos Aires: Siglo xxi, 1973); Enrique Tandeter, “Sobre el análisis de la dominación colonial,” Desarrollo Económico 16, n.º 61 (1976): 151-160.

31On a recent analysis of the political and economic impact of cepal, see Margarita Fajardo, The World That Latin America Created. The United Nations Economic Commission for Latin America in the Development Era (Boston: Harvard University Press, 2021). See also the work of Ruy Mauro Marini, Dialéctica de la dependencia (México: Ediciones Era, 1973) and Subdesarrollo y revolución (México: Siglo xxi Editores, 1974).

32See, for example, Ping-ti Ho, “The Salt Merchants of Yang-Chou: A Study of Commercial Capitalism in Eighteenth-Century China,” Harvard Journal of Asiatic Studies 17, n.º 1/2 (1954): 130-168, doi doi.org/10.2307/2718130; Albert Feuerwerker, “Review: From ‘Feudalism’ to ‘Capitalism’ in Recent Historical Writing from Mainland China,” The Journal of Asian Studies 18, n.º 1 (1958): 107-116, https://doi.org/10.2307/2941290; Étienne Balázs, “The Birth of Capitalism in China,” JESHO 3, n.º 2 (1960): 196-216, doi https://doi.org/10.2307/3596296

33Shiva Chandra Jha, Studies in the Development of Capitalism in India (Calcutta: Firma K. L. Mukhopadhyay, 1963); Vladimir Ivanovich Pavlov, The Indian Capitalist Class: A Historical Study (New Delhi: People’s Publishing House, 1964); Satish Chandra, “Some Aspects of the Growth of a Money Economy in India during the Seventeenth Century,” The Indian Economic and Social History Review 3, n.º 4 (1966 [1962]): 321-31; Balkrishna Govind Gokhale, “Capital Accumulation in XVIIth Century Western India,” Journal of the Asiatic Society of Bombay 39-40, (1964/65): 51-60.

34Maxime Rodinson, Islam and Capitalism (Austin: University of Texas Press, 1978 [1966]); Subhi Y. Labib, “Capitalism in Medieval Islam,” Journal of Economic History 29, n.º 1 (1969): 79-96, doi: https://doi.org/10.1017/S0022050700097837

35Fernando Henrique Cardoso and Enzo Faletto, Dependencia y desarrollo en América Latina. Ensayo de interpretación sociológica (Lima: Instituto de Estudios Peruanos, 1967).

36André Gunder Frank, Latin America: Underdevelopment or Revolution (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1969).

37Horacio Tarcus, dir., Diccionario biográfico de la izquierda argentina. De los anarquistas a la “nueva izquierda” 1870-1976 (Buenos Aires: Emecé, 2007), 36-39. Daniel Gaido y Constanza Bosch Alessio, “Primera aproximación a una interpretación materialista de la historia argentina: ‘Aportes para una historia de la cultura en Argentina’ de Germán Avé-Lallemant (1890),”Revista izquierdas, n.º 15 (2013): 141-169.

38José Carlos Mariátegui, “Esquema de la evolución económica,” in Siete ensayos de interpretación de la realidad peruana (Caracas: Biblioteca de Ayacuho, 2007 [1928]), 7-25.

39Rodolfo Puiggros,De la Colonia a la Revolución(Buenos Aires: Partenon, 1949). See also in the bibliography the works of Andrés Molina Enriquez, Frank Tannenbaum, Luis Chávez Orozco, François Chevalier, Woodrow Borah, Jacques Lamb, Gilberto Freyre, George McBride, Ruggiero Romano and Marcello Carmagnani, among others.

40Carlos Sempat Assadourian, “Modos de producción,” 71-77.

41Ernesto Laclau, “Feudalism and Capitalism in Latin America,” New Left Review 67 (1971), 28.

42Carlos Sempat Assadourian, “Modos de producción, capitalismo y subdesarrollo,” 75.

43Immanuel Wallerstein, The Modern World-System Vol. I: Capitalist Agriculture and the Origins of the European World-Economy in the Sixteenth Century (New York/London: Academic Press, 1974); Vol II: Mercantilism and the Consolidation of the European World-Economy, 1600-1750 (New York: Academic Press, 1980); Vol III: The Second Great Expansion of the Capitalist World-Economy, 1730-1840s (San Diego: Academic Press, 1989); Vol. IV: Centrist Liberalism Triumphant, 1789-1914 (Berkeley: University of California Press, 2011).

44For many decolonial theoreticians, the genesis of decolonial thinking can be ascribed to the encounter between Europe and America, in the 16th century, including the exchange between Guamán Poma de Ayala and Bartolomé de Las Casas, or later, between Fausto Reinaga and Manuel Quintín Lame. Influential forerunners also include 20th century Afro-Caribbean thinkers such as Aimé Césaire and Franz Fanon. For decolonial theory, see, for example Enrique Dussel, El último Marx y la liberación latinoamericana. Un comentario a la tercera y a la cuarta redacción de El Capital (México DF/ Madrid/ Bogotá: Siglo xxi, 1990); Walter Mignolo, The Darker Side of the Renaissance: Literacy, Territoriality, Colonization (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1995) and The Idea of Latin America (Maden/Oxford/Victoria: Blackwell, 2005); Silvia Rivera Cusicanqui, Debates postcoloniales (La Paz: Sephis, 1997); Fernando Coronil, “Más allá del occidentalismo: hacia categorías geohistóricas no-imperiales,” in Teorías sin disciplinas. Latinoamericanismo, poscolonialidad y globalización en debate, edited by Santiago Castro Gómez y Eduardo Mendieta (México: Miguel Ángel Porrúa/Universidad de San Francisco, 1998), 121-146; Aníbal Quijano, “Coloniality of Power and Eurocentrism in Latin America,” International Sociology 15 n.º 2 (2000): 215-232, doi doi.org/10.1177/0268580900015002 and 1492 El encubrimiento del otro: hacia el origen del mito de la modernidad (Buenos Aires: Docencia, 2012 [1992]); Arturo Escobar, Mas allá del Tercer Mundo. Globalización y diferencia (Bogotá: icanh, 2005); Catherine Walsh, Alvaro García and Walter Mignolo (eds.), Interculturalidad, descolonización del Estado y del conocimiento (Buenos Aires: Editorial Signo, 2006); Santiago Castro and Ramón Grosfoguel (eds.), El giro decolonial: reflexiones para una diversidad epistémica más allá del capitalismo global (Bogotá: Siglo del Hombre, 2007).

45Pablo González Casanova, “Sociedad plural, colonialismo interno y desarrollo,” America Latina, Revista del Centro Latinoamericano de Investigaciones en Ciencias Sociales 6, n° 3 (1963): 15-32 and “Internal Colonialism and National Development,” Studies in Comparative International Development 1 (1965): 27-37.

46José Carlos Mariátegui, “El problema del indio en América Latina,” in Siete ensayos, 26-38. Other Latin American intellectuals who put “race” at the center of colonial analyses include: Alcides Arguedas, Raza de Bronce (La Paz: González y Medina, 1919); José Vasconcelos, La raza cósmica (México: Espasa Calpe, 1948[1925]); Rodolfo Kusch, La seducción de la barbarie: análisis herético de un continente mestizo (Buenos Aires: Raigal, 1953).

47Aníbal Quijano, “Prólogo. José Carlos Mariátegui: reencuentro y debate,” in Siete ensayos de interpretación de la realidad peruana. See also Quijano, “Coloniality of Power,” 215-232.

48These include distinguished scholars such as Karl Polanyi, Maurice Dobb, Paul Sweezy, Eric Hobsbawm, Fernand Braudel, Joseph Needham, Gunnar Myrdal, Paul A. Baran, Abdoulaye Ly, Samir Amin, Arghiri Emmanuel, William H. McNeill, Robert Hartwell, Tapan Raychaudhuri, Irfan Habib, Walter Rodney, Abraham Udovitch, Mark Elvin, Douglass C. North, Eric L. Jones, Robert Fogel, Angus Maddison, Perry Anderson, Paul Bairoch, K.N. Chaudhuri, Robert Brenner, Frank Perlin, Philip Huang, Michael Mann, John A. Hall, Charles Tilly, Paul Kennedy, Janet Abu-Lughod, Eric Wolf, Barbara Solow, Stanley Engerman, Patrick K. O’Brien, Sydney W. Mintz, Dale Tomich, Giovanni Arrighi, Robin Blackburn and David Harvey.

49Kaveh Yazdani, “Capitalism - Begriffsgeschichte and Definition of a Concept” (in preparation).

50For some rare exceptions, see Robert Dick, Marriage and Population; their Natural Laws (London: Dyer, 1858), 38: Joaquín Martín de Olías, “Movimiento Obrero en Europa y America Durante el Siglo xix,” Revista Europea 2 (9.8.1874): 170-79, 179; Georges Sorel, “Sur la Théorie Marxiste de la Valeur,” Journal des économistes revue bimensuelle de la science économique et de la statistique 46, n.º 30 (1897): 222-31, 231; Lucien Sanial, “Territorial Expansion,” Socialistic Co-operative Publ. Ass’n 1, n.º 2 (1899): 1-12, 11-2.

51For a much-cited work using the term “capitalisms,” see Richard Whitley, Divergent Capitalisms: The Social Structuring and Change of Business Systems (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999). For a pioneering work using the “varieties of capitalism” framework, see Peter A. Hall and David Soskice (eds.), Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001).

52See, for example, Jack Goody, The East in the West (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press 1996) and Capitalism and Modernity: The Great Debate (Oxford: Polity Press, 2004); Eric Mielants, The Origins of Capitalism and the “Rise of the West” (Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 2007); Giovanni Arrighi, Adam Smith in Beijing: Lineages of the Twenty-first Century (London: Verso, 2007); Henry Heller, The Birth of Capitalism (London: Pluto Press, 2011); Sven Beckert, Empire of Cotton. A Global History (New York: Knopf Doubleday Publishing Group, 2014); Alexander Anievas and Kerem Nişancioğlu, How the West Came to Rule: The Geopolitical Origins of Capitalism (London: Pluto Press, 2015); Jason W. Moore, Capitalism in the Web of Life: Ecology and the Accumulation of Capital (London: Verso Press, 2015); Jürgen Kocka, Capitalism. A Short History (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2016); Steven G. Marks, The Information Nexus: Global Capitalism from the Renaissance to the Present (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2016); Alain Bihr, Le premier âge du capitalisme (1415-1763): L’expansion européenne, 3 Vols. (Lausanne: Syllepse, 2018); Jairus Banaji, A Brief History of Commercial Capitalism (Chicago: Haymarket Books 2020); David McNally, Blood and Money. War, Slavery, Finance, and Empire (Chicago, Haymarket Books, 2020); Thomas Piketty, Capital and Ideology (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2020); Andrew B. Liu, Tea War: A History of Capitalism in China and India (New Haven: Yale University Press, 2020); John M. Hobson, Multicultural Origins of the Global Economy: Beyond the Western-Centric Frontier (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2021); John Shovlin, Trading with the Enemy: Britain, France, and the 18th-Century Quest for a Peaceful World Order (New Haven: Yale University Press, 2021); Zach Sell, Trouble of the World: Slavery and Empire in the Age of Capital (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 2021); Alessandro Stanziani, Capital Terre. Une histoire longue du monde d’après (xiie-xxie siècle) (Paris: Payot, 2021); Heide Gerstenberger, Market and Violence: The Functioning of Capitalism in History (Leiden/Boston: Brill, 2022 [2017]); Ulbe Bosma, The World of Sugar. How the Sweet Stuff Transformed Our Politics, Health, and Environment Over 2,000 Years (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2023).

53For some of the relevant monographs, see Goody, The East in the West and The Eurasian Miracle (Cambridge: John Wiley & Sons, 2010); Jared Diamond, Guns, Germs and Steel: The Fates of Human Societies (New York: W.W. Norton, 1997); André Gunder Frank, ReORIENT: Global Economy in the Asian Age (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1998); David S. Landes, The Wealth and Poverty of Nations: Why Some are so Rich and Some so Poor (London: Little, Brown and Co., 1998); Kenneth Pomeranz, The Great Divergence: China, Europe and the Making of the Modern World (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2000); Joseph E. Inikori, Africans and the Industrial Revolution in England: A Study in International Trade and Economic Development (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2002); John M. Hobson, The Eastern Origins of Western Civilisation (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2004); Angus Maddison, Contours of the World Economy, I—2030 AD: Essays in Macro-Economic History (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2007); Robert Marks, The Origins of the Modern World: Fate and Fortune in the Rise of the West (Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, 2007); Gregory Clark, A Farewell to Alms: A Brief Economic History of the World (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2007); Jack A. Goldstone, Why Europe? The Rise of the West in World History, 1500- 1800 (Boston: McGraw-Hill Education, 2008); Robert C. Allen, The British Industrial Revolution in Global Perspective (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2009); Ronald Findlay and Kevin H. O’Rourke, Power and Plenty: Trade, War, and the World Economy in the Second Millennium (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2009); Victor Lieberman, Strange Parallels: Southeast Asia in Global Context, c.800-1830, Vol. 2 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2009); Jan Luiten Van Zanden, The Long Road to the Industrial Revolution: The European Economy in a Global Perspective, 1000-1800 (Leiden: Brill, 2009); Timur Kuran, The Long Divergence: How Islamic Law Held Back the Middle East (New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 2010); Ian Morris, Why the West Rules-for Now: The Patterns of History and what they Reveal about the Future (London: Profile Books, 2010); Prasannan Parthasarathi, Why Europe Grew Rich and Asia Did Not: Global Economic Divergence, 1600-1850 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2011); Niall Ferguson, Civilization: The West and the Rest (London: Penguin, 2011); Jean-Laurent Rosenthal and Roy Bin Wong, Before and Beyond Divergence: The Politics of Economic Change in China and Europe (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2011); Jeffrey G. Williamson, Trade and Poverty: When the Third World Fell Behind (Cambridge: Massachusetts Institute of Technology Press, 2011); Ricardo Duchesne, The Uniqueness of Western Civilization (Leiden: Brill, 2011); Daron Acemoglu and James A. Robinson, Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity and Poverty (London: Crown Publishing Group, 2012); Peer Vries, Escaping Poverty: The Origins of Modern Economic Growth (Vienna: Vandenhoeck & Ruprecht, 2013) and State, Economy and the Great Divergence. Great Britain and China, 1680s to 1850s (London: Bloomsbury Publishing, 2015); Leonid E. Grinin and Andrey V. Korotayev, Great Divergence and Great Convergence: A Global Perspective (Cham: Springer, 2015); Philip T. Hoffman, Why Did Europe Conquer the World? (New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 2015); Joel Mokyr, A Culture of Growth: The Origins of the Modern Economy (New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 2016); Deirdre N. McCloskey, Bourgeois Equality: How Ideas, Not Capital or Institutions, Enriched the World (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2016); Tonio Andrade, The Gunpowder Age: China, Military Innovation, and the Rise of the West in World History (New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 2016); Kaveh Yazdani, India, Modernity and the Great Divergence. Mysore and Gujarat (17th to 18th C.) (Leiden: Brill, 2017); William J. Ashworth, The Industrial Revolution: The State, Knowledge and Global Trade (London: Bloomsbury Publishing, 2017); Priya Satia, Empire of Guns: The Violent Making of the Industrial Revolution (New York: Penguin, 2018); Walter Scheidel, Escape from Rome: The Failure of Empire and the Road to Prosperity (New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 2019); Jason C. Sharman, Empires of the Weak: The Real Story of European Expansion and the Creation of the New World Order (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2019); Jonathan Daly, How Europe Made the Modern World: Creating the Great Divergence (London: Bloomsbury, 2020); Oded Galor, The Journey of Humanity. The Origins of Wealth and Inequality (New York: Penguin, 2022); Mark Koyama and Jared Rubin, How the World Became Rich: The Historical Origins of Economic Growth (Cambridge: Polity Press, 2022).

54Mohajer and Yazdani, “Reading Marx,” 237-8.

55For Japan, Egypt, Safavid Iran and South East Asia, see the respective chapters in Kaveh Yazdani and Dilip Menon (eds.), Capitalisms: Towards a Global History (Delhi: Oxford University Press, 2020). For Argentina, see Jeremy Adelman, Republic of Capital: Buenos Aires and the Legal Transformation of the Atlantic World (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1999). For Mexico, see John Tutino, Making a New World: Founding Capitalism in the Bajío and Spanish North America (Durham/London: Duke University Press, 2011) and The Mexican Heartland: How Communities Shaped Capitalism, a Nation, and World History, 1500-2000 (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2018); Emilio Kourí, A Pueblo Divided: Business, Property and Community in Papantla, Mexico (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 2004). For Perú and Bolivia see, Jason Moore, “‘This lofty mountain of silver could conquer the whole world’: Potosí and the political ecology of underdevelopment, 1545-1800,” The Journal of Philosophical Economics 4, n.º 1 (2010), 58-103, doi 10.46298/jpe.10605; Kris Lane, Potosí: The Silver City That Changed the World(University of California Press, 2019); Paula C. Zagalsky and Rossana Barragán, (eds.) Potosí in the Global Silver Age (16th—19th Centuries) (Leiden: Brill, 2023).

56For gender and “race” see Jennifer L. Morgan, Reckoning with Slavery. Gender, Kinship, and Capitalism in the Early Black Atlantic (Durham, Duke University Press, 2021); Diana Paton, “Gender History, Global History, and Atlantic Slavery. On Racial Capitalism and Social Reproduction,” The American Historical Review 127, n.º 2 (2022): 726-754, doi 10.1093/ahr/rhac156. For non-US-centric histories of racial capitalism see Cedric J. Robinson, Black Marxism: The Making of the Black Radical Tradition (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 2000 [1983]); Michael Ralph and Maya Singhal, “Racial capitalism,” Theory and Society 48 (2019): 851-881, doi 10.1007/s11186-019-09367-z; Julian Go, “Three Tensions in the Theory of Racial Capitalism,” Sociological Theory 39, n.º 1 (2021): 38-47 doi doi.org/10.1177/0735275120979822; Catherine Hall, “Racial Capitalism: What’s in a Name?,” History Workshop Journal 94 (2022): 1-17, doi https://doi.org/10.1093/hwj/dbac022; Onur Ulas Ince, “Deprovincializing racial capitalism: John Crawfurd and settler colonialism in India,” American Political Science Review 116, n.º 1 (2022): 144-160; Anna More, “The Early Portuguese Slave Ship and the Infrastructure of Racial Capitalism,” Social Text 40, n.º 4 (2022): 17-41, doi doi.org/10.1215/01642472-10013290; William Conroy, “Race, Capitalism, and the Necessity/Contingency Debate,” Theory, Culture & Society (2022): 1-19. Online: doi doi.org/10.1177/02632764221140780; Houssam Hamade and Christoph Sorg, “Rassismus und Kapitalismus,” in Rassismusforschung I. Theoretische und interdisziplinäre Perspektiven, edited by Nationaler Diskriminierungs- und Rassismusmonitor (Bielefeld: transcript, 2023): 251-91. For an emphasis on ecology see Jason W. Moore: Capitalism in the Web of Life and Anthropocene or Capitalocene? Nature, History, and the Crisis of Capitalism (Oakland: PM Press, 2016); John Bellamy Foster and Brett Clark, The Robbery of Nature: Capitalism and the Ecological Rift (New York: Monthly Review Press, 2020). For an overview, see also Jens Marquardt, “Worlds apart? The Global South and the Anthropocene,” in The Anthropocene Debate and Political Science, edited by Thomas Hickmann, Lena Partzsch, Philipp Pattberg, Sabine Weiland (New York: Routledge, 2019), 200-218.

57Larry Neil and Jeffrey G. Williamson (eds.), The Cambridge History of Capitalism, 2 Vols. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2014).

58See, for example, Jürgen Kocka and Marcel van der Linden (eds.), Capitalism: The Reemergence of a Historical Concept (London: Bloomsbury, 2016); Lukas Rieppel et al. (eds.), Science and Capitalism: Entangled Histories, Osiris 33 (2018); Daniel Nemser and John D. Blanco (eds.), Capitalism-Catholicism-Colonialism, Journal for Early Modern Cultural Studies 19, n.º 2 (2019); Yazdani and Menon (eds.), Capitalisms; Catherine Casson and Philipp Robinson Rössner (eds.), Evolutions of Capitalism: Historical Perspectives, 1200-2000 (Bristol: Bristol University Press, 2022).

59Xavier Lafrance and Charles Post (eds.), Case Studies in the Origins of Capitalism (Cham: Springer, 2019). See also Robert Brenner, “Agrarian Class Structure and Economic Development in Pre-industrial Europe,” in The Brenner Debate: Agrarian Class Structure and Economic Development in Pre-Industrial Europe, edited by Trevor Henry Aston and Charles H. E. Philpin (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985): 10-63; Ellen Meiksins Wood, The Origins of Capitalism: A Longer View (London: Verso, 2002).

60Karl Marx, Capital: A Critique of Political Economy, Vol. 2 (London: Penguin, 1992 [1885]), chapter 1.

61Henry Heller, for instance, misleadingly argues that the “creation of value without the personal freedom to sell one’s labour power is unthinkable” and that slavery and indentured labor are per se pre-capitalist. Henry Heller, A Marxist History of Capitalism (New York: Routledge, 2019), 16. For similar Marxist misconceptions, see David Harvey, A Companion to Marx’s Capital (Vol. 1), (London: Verso, 2010), 127; Patrick Murray, The Mismeasure of Wealth: Essays on Marx and Social Form (Leiden: Brill, 2016), 187-8; Nick Nesbitt, The Price of Slavery Capitalism and Revolution in the Caribbean (University of Virginia Press Charlottesville, 2022). For a brief summary of Marx’s distinct analysis of modern plantation slavery and a differing Marxian classification of modern slave labor, see Kaveh Yazdani, “Capitalism, Slavery,” 492-3. See also John Clegg, “A Theory of Capitalist Slavery,” Journal of Historical Sociology 33, n.º 1 (2020): 74-98, 86 and Tâmis Parron in the present volume.

62This definition has been drawn mainly from Yazdani, “Capitalism, Slavery,” 474-5.

63Kaveh Yazdani, “Dadani,” in Changing Theory: Concepts from the Global South, edited by Dilip Menon (Routledge: New York, 2022): 181-196, 192. As Marx pointed out, in many historical phases, “commercial capital is synonymous with the non-subjection of production to capital.” Karl Marx, Capital. A Critique of Political Economy, Vol. 3 (London: Penguin Books, 1993[1894]), 445, 438, 442. See also Banaji, A Brief History; Shinya Shibasaki and Kei Ehara, “What is commercial capital? Japanese contributions to Marxian market theory,” Capital & Class 46, n.º 2 (2022): 235-256. By Smithian growth, we mean the episodic or cyclic “expansion of economic activity accompanying the extension of specialization and the division of labor, caused by a widening of markets due to the removal of artificial barriers, possibly along with a succession of discrete innovations in agriculture, manufacturing, and transport.” Findlay and O’Rourke, Power and Plenty, 338.

64Some of the pioneering studies on what Raymond de Roover later termed “the Commercial Revolution of the Middle Ages,” include Heinrich Sieveking, Die rheinischen Gemeinden Erpel und Unkel und ihre Entwickelung im 14. und 15. Jahrhundert (Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot, 1895); Alfred Doren, Entwicklung und Organisation der Florentiner Zünfte im 13. und 14. Jahrhundert (Leipzig: Duncker und Humblot, 1897); Henri Pirenne, “The Stages in the History of Capitalism,” American Historical Review 19, n.º 3 (1914): 494-515 and Medieval Cities: Their Origins and the Revival of Trade, trans. Frank D. Halsey (Princeton, 1925); Lujo Brentano, Die Anfänge des modernen Kapitalismus: Festrede gehalten in der öffentlichen Sitzung der K. Akademie der Wissenschaften am 15. März 1913 (Munich: Verlag der K. B. Akademie der Wissenschaften,1916); Jacob Strieder, “Origin and Evolution of Early European Capitalism,” Journal of Economic and Business History 2, (1929): 1-19; Robert S. Lopez, The Commercial Revolution of the Middle Ages, 950-1350 (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, Inc., 1971). See also Francesca Trivellato, “Renaissance Florence and the Origins of Capitalism: A Business History Perspective,” Business History Review 94, n.º 1 (2020): 229-251.

65The dadani system was a South Asian mode of organizing economic production. It became dominant during the 17th and 18th centuries and bore both similarities and differences to the European putting-out systems of that period. See also Ghulam Nadri in this volume.

66Marx, Capital, Vol. 1, 873-940. For a critical assessment of the so-called primitive accumulation, see Mohajer and Yazdani, “Reading Marx in the Divergence Debate.” For a less sketchy periodization, see Kaveh Yazdani, “The Biography of capitalism” (in preparation).

67Mohajer and Yazdani, “Reading Marx in the Divergence Debate.”

68For recent works on West Asia and the Ottoman Empire, see, for example, Mahmood Ibrahim, Merchant Capital and Islam (Austin: University of Texas Press, 1990); Gene W. Heck, Charlemagne, Muhammad and the Arab Roots of Capitalism (Berlin: Walter de Gruyter, 2006); Jairus Banaji, “Islam, the Mediterranean and the Rise of Capitalism,” Historical Materialism 15, n.º 1 (2007): 47-74, doi.org/10.1163/156920607x171591 and A Brief History, 125-38; Kuran, The Long Divergence; Şevket Pamuk, “Institutional Change and Economic Development in the Middle East, 700- 1800,” in The Cambridge History of Capitalism, Vol. 1, edited by Larry Neal (Cambridge University Press, 2014) 193-224; Benedikt Koehler, Early Islam and the Birth of Capitalism (Lanham: Lexington Books, 2014); Deniz T. Kilinçoğlu, Economics and Capitalism in the Ottoman Empire (Abingdon: Routledge 2015); John Mathew, Margins of the market: Trafficking and capitalism across the Arabian Sea (Berkeley: University of California Press 2016). For Egypt, see, for example, Peter Gran, Islamic Roots of Capitalism: Egypt, 1760-1840 (Austin: University of Texas Press, 1979); Nelly Hanna, Artisan entrepreneurs in Cairo and early-modern capitalism (1600-1800) (Syracuse: Syracuse University Press, 2011); Aaron G. Jakes, Egypt’s Occupation: Colonial Economism and the Crises of Capitalism (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 2020). For longue durée histories of capitalism in West Asia, see Murat Çızakça, Islamic Capitalism and Finance: Origins, Evolution and the Future (Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar, 2011); Mehrdad Vahabi, Destructive Coordination, Anfal and Islamic Political Capitalism. A New Reading of Contemporary Iran (Cham: Springer, 2023).

69For recent publications, see, for example, Richard von Glahn, “The Changing Significance of Latin American Silver in the Chinese Economy, 16th-19th Centuries,” Revista de Historia Economica - Journal of Iberian and Latin American Economic History 38, n.º 3 (2019): 553-585, doi10.1017/S0212610919000193; Renate Pieper, Claudia de Lozanne Jefferies and Markus Denzel, Mining, Money and Markets in the Early Modern Atlantic (Cham: Palgrave Macmillan, 2019); Akinobu Kuroda, A Global History of Money (Abingdon: Routledge, 2020); Dennis O. Flynn, “Silver, Globalization and Capitalism,” in Capitalisms, edited by Yazdani and Menon, 35-70; Lin Sun et al., “Global circulation of silver between Ming-Qing China and the Americas: Combining historical texts and scientific analyses,” archaeometry 63, n.º 3 (2021), 627-640, doi /doi.org/10.1111/arcm.12617; Arturo Giráldez, “Monetary Flows and Currency Management in Ming-Qing,” in Oxford Research Encyclopedias: Asian History, edited by David Ludden (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2022), Online: doi.org/10.1093/acrefore/9780190277727.013.625; Sergio T. Serrano Hernández, “Producing Gold and Silver to Globalize the Economy during the Early Modern Era: San Luis Potosi and the Pacific Trade with Asia,” Asian Review of World Histories 10, n.º 1 (2022): 58-96, doi doi.org/10.1163/22879811-12340104

70See, for example, Hill Gates, China’s Motor: A Thousand Years of Petty Capitalism (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1996); Robert Marks, “Commercialization without Capitalism: Processes of Environmental Change in South China, 1550-1850,” Environmental History 1, n.º 1 (1996): 56-82; Roy Bin Wong, China Transformed. Historical Change and the Limits of European Experience (Ithaca and London: Cornell University Press, 1997) and “China before capitalism,” in The Cambridge History of Capitalism, Vol. 1, 125-164; Kent Deng, The Chinese Premodern Economy: Structural Equilibrium and Capitalist Sterility (London: Routledge Press, 1999) and “One-Off Capitalism in Song China, 960-1279 AD,” in Capitalisms, 227-250; Xu Dixin and Wu Chengming, Chinese Capitalism, 1522-1840 (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 2000); Pomeranz, The Great Divergence; David Faure, China and Capitalism. A History of Business Enterprise in Modern China (Hong Kong: Hong Kong University Press, 2006), 11-25; Ho-Fung Hung, The China Boom: Why China Will Not Rule the World (New York: Columbia University Press, 2015), 15-33; Rebecca E. Karl, The Magic of Concepts History and the Economic in Twentieth-Century China (Durham: Duke University Press, 2017): 40-72; Anne Gerritsen, “The View from Early Modern China Capitalism and the Jingdezhen Ceramics Industry,” Capitalisms, 306-326; Luman Wang, Chinese Hinterland Capitalism and Shanxi Piaohao Banking, State, and Family, 1720-1910 (Abingdon: Routledge, 2021); Ying-shih Yü, The Religious Ethic and Mercantile Spirit in Early Modern China (New York, Colombia University Press, 2021); Pengsheng Chiu, “Commercialization in Late Ming China: Seeds of Capitalism?,” Oxford Research Encyclopedia: Asian History (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2022), Online: doi.org/10.1093/acrefore/9780190277727.013.619

71See, for example, Gokhale, “Capital Accumulation”; Surendra Gopal, Commerce and Crafts in Gujarat, 16th and 17th Centuries: A Study in the Impact of European Expansion on Precapitalist Economy (New Delhi: People’s Publishing House 1975); David Hardiman, “Penetration of merchant capital in pre-colonial Gujarat,” in Capitalist Development: Critical Essays, edited by Ghanshyam Shah (Bombay: Popular Prakashan 1990), 29-44; Kaveh Yazdani, India, Modernity and the Great Divergence: Mysore and Gujarat (17th to 19th Century); Samira Sheikh, “Jibhabhu’s Rights to Ghee: Land control and vernacular capitalism in Gujarat, circa 1803-10,” Modern Asian Studies 51, n.º 2 (2017): 350-374, doi https://doi.org/10.1017/S0026749X16000718; Douglas E. Haynes, “Vernacular Capitalism, Advertising, and the Bazaar in Early Twentieth-Century Western India,” in Rethinking Markets in Modern India Embedded Exchange and Contested Jurisdiction, edited by Ajay Gandhi, et al. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2020), 116-146; Michael O’Sullivan, “Vernacular Capitalism and Intellectual History in a Gujarati Account of China, 1860-68,” The Journal of Asian Studies 80, n.º 2 (2021): 267-292, doi https://doi.org/10.1017/S0021911820003678

72See, for example, John Iliffe, The Emergence of African Capitalism (London: Macmillan, 1983); Joseph C. Miller, Way of death: merchant capitalism and the Angolan slave trade, 1730-1830 (Madison, University of Wisconsin Press, 1988); Frederick Cooper, Africa in the World: Capitalism, Empire, Nation-State (Cambridge, Harvard University Press, 2014); Morten Jerven, “The Emergence of Capitalism in Africa,” in The Cambridge History of Capitalism, Vol. 1, 431-454; Joseph E. Inikori, “Euro-African Trade Relations and Socioeconomic Development in West Africa, 1450-1900,” Oxford Research Encyclopedia: African History (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2019), doi https://doi.org/10.1093/acrefore/9780190277734.013.276; Keith Breckenridge, “What happened to the theory of African capitalism?,” Economy and Society 50, n.º 1 (2021): 9-35, doi doi.org/10.1080/03085147.2021.1841928; Toby Green, “Africa and Capitalism: Repairing a History of Omission,” Capitalism: A Journal of History and Economics 3, n.º 2 (2022), 301-332, doi:10.1353/cap.2022.0012; Mariana P. Candido, “Capitalism and Africa: Revisiting Way of Death Thirty-Five Years after its Publication,” American Historical Review 127, n.º 3 (2022): 1439-1448, doi https://doi.org/10.1093/ahr/rhac266

73See, for example, Pedro Machado, Ocean of Trade: South Asian Merchants, Africa and the Indian Ocean, c. 1750-1850 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2014); Fahad Bishara and Hollian Wint, “Into the bazaar: Indian Ocean vernaculars in the age of global capitalism,” Journal of Global History 16, n.º 1 (2020), 44-64, doi, doi:10.1017/S174002282000011X

74For recent non-US-centric histories, see, for example, Olivier Pétré-Grenouilleau, L’argent de la traite. Milieu négrier, capitalisme et development: un modèle (Paris: Aubier, 1996); Robin Blackburn, The Making of New World Slavery: From the Baroque to the Modern, 1492-1800 (London: Verso, 1997); Trevor Burnard and John Garrigus, The Plantation Machine: Atlantic Capitalism in French Saint-Domingue and British Jamaica (Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press, 2016); Paul Cheney, Cul de Sac: Patrimony, Capitalism, and Slavery in French Saint-Domingue (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2017); Dale Tomich (ed.), Slavery and Historical Capitalism During the Nineteenth Century (Lanham: Lexington Books, 2017); Eduardo Grüner, The Haitian Revolution: Capitalism, Slavery, and Counter-Modernity (Cambridge: Polity, 2020 [2017]); Daniel Rood, The Reinvention of Atlantic Slavery: Technology, Labor, Race and Capitalism in the Greater Caribbean (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2020); Stephan Conermann and Michael Zeuske (eds.), The Slavery / Capitalism Debate Global. From “Capitalism and Slavery” to Slavery as Capitalism, Comparativ 30, n.º 5/6 (2020); Joseph E. Inikori, “Atlantic Slavery and the Rise of the Capitalist Global Economy,” Current Anthropology 61, n.º 22 (2020): 59-71, doi https://doi.org/10.1086/710707; Trevor Burnard and Giorgio Riello, “Slavery and the new history of capitalism,” The Journal of Global History 15, n.º 2 (2020): 225-244, doi 10.1017/S1740022820000029; Anthony Bogues, “How Much Is Your African Slave Worth?,” differences 31, n.º 3 (2020): 156-168, doi:10.1215/10407391-8744567; Nuala Zahedieh, “Eric Williams and William Forbes: Copper, colonial markets and commercial capitalism,” The Economic History Review 74, n.º 3 (2021): 784-808, doi https://doi.org/10.1111/ehr.13050; Leonardo Marques, “Slavery and Capitalism,” in The SAGE Handbook of Marxism edited by Beverley Skeggs et al. (London: SAGE, 2022), 248-267; David Pretel, “Capitalismo y esclavitud: Nuevas historias, viejos debates,” Ayer 126, n.º 2 (2022): 331-345, doi https://doi.org/10.55509/ayer/886

75Several reviews and critical assessments of the book are available, including by Barbara Harriss-White, Henry Bernstein, Tom Brass, Henry Heller, Laleh Khalili, Adam Tooze, James Parisot, Srinath Raghavan, Morteza Samanpour, Pete Green, Lord Desai, Nick Evans and Ksenia Arapko. See also the discussion of Banaji’s book in Lorenzo M. Bondioli, Paolo Tedesco and Michele Campopiano (eds.), Commercial Capitalism and Global History, Storica xxviii, n. º 83-84 (2022-23). The volume includes articles by Paolo Tedesco, Martha C. Howell, Priya Satia, Lorenzo Bondioli, Andrew Liu and Sheetal Chhabria. For one of the few Spanish receptions of Banaji’s work, see Marcelo Emiliano Perelman Fajardo, “Reseña de A Brief History of Commercial Capitalism,” Antagónica. Revista de investigación y crítica social, n.º 3 (2021): 147-158.

How to cite: Yazdani, Kaveh and Constanza Castro. “Capitalisms of the ‘Global South’ (c. 10th to 19th Centuries) - Old and New Contributions and Debates,” Historia Crítica n.° 89 (2023): 3-41, doi: https://doi.org/10.7440/histcrit89.2023.01

Received: April 24, 2023; Accepted: May 13, 2023

Creative Commons License This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License