SciELO - Scientific Electronic Library Online

 
 issue29Immigrant Entrepreneurs, Bread, and Worker Protest in Porfirian Mexico City: os empresários basconavarros e a mobilização operáriaFourth-rate meat for fourth-rate consumers author indexsubject indexarticles search
Home Pagealphabetic serial listing  

Services on Demand

Journal

Article

Indicators

Related links

  • On index processCited by Google
  • Have no similar articlesSimilars in SciELO
  • On index processSimilars in Google

Share


Revista de Estudios Sociales

Print version ISSN 0123-885X

rev.estud.soc.  no.29 Bogotá Jan./Apr. 2008

 

Mucha res y poco cerdo: el consumo de la carne en Colombia*

When Beef Was King. Or Why Do Colombians Eat so Little Pork?

Muita carne de vaca e pouca de porco: o consumo da carne na Colômbia

Shawn Van Ausdal**

* I want to thank Alberto Flórez, Stefania Gallini, Ingrid Bolívar, and Luis Guillermo Baptiste for stimulating discussions about meat consumption in Colombia, and planting the seed from which this article eventually grew. I also want to acknowledge Juan Ignacio Arboleda for his assistance in researching this piece; and thank Claudia Leal, Alejandro Guarín, and two anonymous reviewers fortheir helpful comments on earlier versions of this article.

** Ph.D. candidate, Dept. of Geography, University of California, Berkeley. Currently finishing an historical geography of cattle ranching in Colombia, and recently published Medio Siglo de Geografía Histórica en Norteamérica in Historia Crítica, 32(2006). E-mail: s_vanausdal@yahoo.com


Resumen

Este artículo busca explicar por qué los colombianos han comido más carne de res que de cerdo en comparación con otros latinoamericanos. Comienza examinando el desarrollo de una tradición culinaria que favorece la carne de res. El eje central del argumento, sin embargo, es que la carne de res ha sido, históricamente, bastante más barata que la de cerdo. Esta diferencia de precio está ligada al alto costo del maíz, que suele emplearse para la ceba de cerdos, debido a la baja productividad de la agricultura colombiana. Otros factores que favorecieron a la carne de res incluyen una frontera agraria en retroceso, una población de cerdos pequeña, las ventajas de la ganadería, la monopolización de la tierra, la influencia de la importación de manteca de cerdo y el desarrollo de una industria de aceite vegetal.

Palabras clave: Consumo de carne, estudios de la comida, cría de cerdos, ganadería, agricultura, Colombia.


Abstract

This article seeks to understand why Colombians, compared to many other Latin Americans, have traditionally eaten so much more beef than pork. The article first pointstothe development of a culinary tradition thatfavored beef. The bulkof the argument, though, centers on the fact that, historically, beef has been substantially cheaper than pork. This price difference, in turn, is rooted in the low productivity of Colombian agriculture, which made corn, often used to fatten hogs, expensive. Additional factors that favored beef include a receding agrarian frontier, a small hog population, the various advantages of cattle, a conflictridden history of land monopolization, and the influence of lard imports and the subsequent development of a vegetable oil industry.

Key words: Meat consumption, food studies, hog raising, cattle ranching, agriculture, Colombia.


Resumo

O objetivo deste artigo é explicar o motivo pelo qual os colombianos vêm comendo mais carne de vaca do que de porco em comparação com outros latinoamericanos. O texto começa examinando o desenvolvimento de uma tradição culinária que privilegia a carne de vaca. No entanto, o eixo central do argumento é que a carne de vaca tem sido historicamente muito mais econômica do que a de porco. Esta diferença de preço tem relação com o alto custo do milho, que costuma ser empregado para o engorde dos porcos, devido à baixa produtividade da agricultura colombiana. Outros fatores que favoreceram a tradição culinária da carne são: o contexto de uma fronteira agrária em retrocesso, uma baixa população de porcos, a vantagem da pecuária, a monopolização da terra, a influência da importação da banha de porco e o desenvolvimento de uma indústria de óleo vegetal.

Palavras chave: Consumo de carne; estudos da comida, criação de porcos, pecuária, agricultura, Colombia.


In 2007, Colombia ceased to be primarily a beef- eating nation (El Tiempo, 2007).1 The change was significant. For generations, possibly even since the early colonial period, Colombians consumed much more beef than any other meat. For every pound of lechona, fritanga, chicharrón, or other form of pork that Colombians have savored since the late-nineteenth century, they have eaten between five and seven pounds of beef (see Figure 1). To give some perspective, in the United States, the ratio of pork-to-beef consumption has been about 1-to- 1.5 since 1950 (Skaggs, 1986, pp. 166167; FAOSTAT, 2007). Even in Latin America, which has long been cattle country, Colombia's beef-heavy meat diet has been extreme. At least since 1960, Colombians have been, in relative terms, the largest beef-eaters in tropical Latin America (see Figures 2 and 3). (They have also been, in absolute terms, one of the largest beef consumers per capita in the region.) Consequently, Colombians have consumed much less pork, proportionally, than many other Latin Americans. Whereas pork has comprised between a fifth and a third of the meat diet in Brazil and Mexico since 1950, in Colombia it has hovered around ten percent (United Nations, 1962, p. 45; United Nations, 1964, p. 50; Jarvis, 1986, p. 2; FAOSTAT, 2007). This article marks the end of an era by asking two related questions: why, historically, have Colombians eaten so little pork? And what accounted for the long predominance of beef?

Although a variety of factors converged to make Colombia a beef-eating nation, I suggest that it was the historic high cost of pork that played a fundamental role. Much of this article, therefore, is an effort to explain why beef has been cheaper than pork. I argue that, in the case of Colombia since the mid-nineteenth century, it was not cheap, natural grasslands that made beef less expensive, as commonly suggested, but the low productivity of Colombian agriculture. What I consciously downplay here is the cultural or social status that beef may have had in determining meat consumption patterns. In fact, this article originated in a frustrated effort to identify pro-beef discourses in the first half of the twentieth century (Flórez, forthcoming). To explain why Colombians eat so much more beef than pork, I turn away from recent trends in food studies, which underline the symbolic aspects and cultural politics of food, to emphasize production and price (Watson and Caldwell, 2005). It is possible that the symbolic value of beef played a greater role than I allow, but overall I do not think that it was that critical.

Three general ideas structure this paper. Lest I get too carried away with my price-centered argument, in the first section I examine the development of a culinary tradition that favored beef. There are hints of a deeply-rooted tradition of meat consumption in Colombia, despite the obvious social inequalities and important variations over time and space. Since beef appears to have been the most common meat, a form of dietary inertia developed around it. Tradition, however, can only explain so much. In the second section, therefore, I turn to the comparative advantage of grass. My argument, as noted above, is that the historic predominance of beef largely stemmed from the high cost of pork, which in turn was a consequence of the high cost of corn and the low productivity of Colombian agriculture. Despite the recurring criticisms of Colombian ranching as extensive and inefficient, grass and cattle gave beef some advantages over other meats. In the last section, I examine how the agrarian structure and government policies also conspired against a richer tradition of pork consumption: the former by constraining peasant production; the latter by undercutting the market for lard.

A tradition of beef

Tradition is a tricky word since many so-called traditions are actually practices of fairly recent origin that were "invented" to naturalize specific interests (Hobsbawm and Ranger, 1992). Nonetheless, in this section I suggest that part of the historic predominance of beef consumption in Colombia has to do simply with the development of a culinary tradition in which beef played an important role: Colombians have favored beef because it is what they grew up eating, what they learned to cook, and what they came to expect.

The Colombian taste for beef emerged within a wider Latin American tradition stretching back to the early colonial period. It is possible that the Spanish exported a penchant for beef from Andalusia along with the cultural practice of raising cattle from horseback on the open range (Bishko, 1952; Jordan, 1993). But key to the place of beef in colonial diets was the rapid proliferation of cattle in New World environments. Free from major predators, Old World diseases, and ecological competition, cattle multiplied quickly on the region's grasslands. The precipitous decline of native populations, in part a result of growing herds, opened up yet more space for livestock and helped create an abundance of animals relative to consumers (Crosby, 1972; Melville, 1994). In some areas, such as the Pampas and Northern Mexico, local residents could not eat all the cattle they culled. There, they extracted more value from hides and tallow than meat (Pilcher, 2006, p. 30; Barsky and Gelman, 2001, p. 59). Even outside these areas, beef consumption could be remarkably high. European visitors were often astonished at the large quantities of meat that Latin Americans ate (Pilcher, 2006, p. 18). Colonial Caracas, for instance, is said to have consumed 50 percent more beef than Paris even though it had only ten percent of the population (Rifkin, 1992, p. 49).

Not everyone, however, had easy access to beef or other kinds of meat. Although cattle adapted to a wide variety of environments, they did not multiply with the same fecundity everywhere. For instance, cattle herds expanded more slowly on the Llanos, the great natural grasslands of Colombia and Venezuela (characterized by climatic extremes of searing heat and flooding, abundant but poor quality grasses, and natural predators), than in the temperate and benign Pampas (Crosby, 1972; Rausch, 1984; Rausch 1993). In many other regions, vast tracts of tropical forest limited the geographic and biological expansion of cattle. The miners of northeastern Antioquia, therefore, ate cattle bred in the distant Valle del Cauca, fattened on the highland pastures of Rionegro, and driven to slaughter in the mines amidst lowland forests (West, 1952, pp. 11215; Parsons, 1968, pp. 12728). Also, the initial population explosion did not last indefinitely: as their pressure on rangelands increased, the growth rates of herds tapered. By the late-eighteenth century, a growing demand for cattle -from expanding human populations, economic growth, and increased trade- began to squeeze existing stocks, causing prices to rise rather substantially (Sourdis, 1996, pp. 4445; Brungardt, 1974; Pilcher, 2006, pp. 2728). Beef, therefore, was not always in great abundance and inexpensive. Jeffrey Pilcher (2006, pp. 16, 22) reminds us that while the Mexican elite dined on exaggerated quantities of meat, the rural poor retained a largely vegetarian diet that pre-dated the Spanish conquest. In Colombia, highland peasants also appear to have eaten little meat up to the end of the nineteenth century (Camacho Roldán, 1946, p. 131; Meisel and Vega, 2004, p. 12).

Nonetheless, there is scattered evidence to suggest that meat consumption in Colombia was fairly widespread. While the overall quantities may have been small, and consumption erratic, I suspect that it was sufficient to make meat -particularly beef- a key component of the national diet and culinary imagination. Robert West (1952, p. 112), in his study of mining in colonial Colombia, was surprised at the "large quantity of meat" that miners ate. Mining ordinances from the seventeenth century required that Indian laborers be given 12 pounds of meat each per week (West, 1952, p. 95; Calero, 1997, p. 147; see also Taussig, 1977, p. 403; Hamilton, 1993, p. 291, 312). Even if the ordinances were not enforced, the stipulation that daily rations include almost two pounds of meat underlines its abundance. The half-rations of meat stipulated in case of a siege of Cartagena in the mid-eighteenth century (for the militia, artisans, and workers) included six ounces of beef and two ounces of bacon (tocino) per day (Dorta, 1962, pp. 351-352). Fray Juan de Santa Gertrudis (Serra, 1994, pp. 67-68) remarked that for "ordinary people" of the coastal lowlands "the common food.... is generally just a stew of beef jerky and...yucca, arracacha, sweet potato, cassava or ñame root and sapallo2." Other eighteenth -and nineteenth-century accounts also note that meals outside the highlands were "almost always accompanied by a piece of beef, no matter how dry and hard it might be" (Hettner, 1976, p. 219; see also Vargas, 1944, pp. 1112; Holton, 1967, pp. 2526, 198; Striffler, 1994, p. 175; Hamilton, 1993,pp. 40, 62, 115, 335). For the highlands, Vargas (1944, pp. 136-137) calculated that an ordinary daily ration in a hospital in Zipaquirá should include one pound of beef and one ounce of bacon, but he acknowledged that many people would be unable to afford it. Urban laborers appear to have eaten some meat, but by most ac counts highland peasants consumed little (Boussingault, 1994,pp. 365,367).

The expansion of the export economy from the mid- nineteenth century did much to increase beef consumption and solidify its place in the culinary imagination. The demand for workers in the tobacco fields and on public works projects increased wages in both the lowlands and highlands and "introduced beef consumption to the working class" (Camacho Roldán, 1946, p. 167; Rivas, 1983, p. 212; Nieto Arteta, 1996, pp. 262263). Towards the end of the century, Camacho Roldán (1946, p. 164) thought that beef consumption was "one of the items whose consumption has improved notably..." (see also Arboleda, 1905, pp. 96116). By this time, cattle ranchers knew that good coffee prices translated into robust demand for their animals (APNOyC, [Folder] 170, p. 473; APNOyC, 200, p. 364). Daily rations for agricultural laborers in Antioquia included between two and eight ounces of beef; miners could get 24 ounces (Pérez, 1915, p. 105; APNOyC, 200, Jan. 13, 1916 and Jan. 14, 1916; Poveda, 1979, p. 120; Brew, 2000, p. 174). The department of Bolívar even provided prisoners in the jail in Cartagena with half-a-pound of meat per day.3 A taste for beef also likely spread through the rations that soldiers received (and requisitioned) in the frequent civil wars of the nineteenth century.4 By the early-twentieth century, the general pattern of meat consumption that would last for much of the rest of the century, both in terms of quantity and kind, was already well-established (see Figure 1).5

The above consumption rates are somewhat misleading, though. They suggest, multiplied over the course of a year, that some Colombian laborers and even prisoners ate more meat, and considerably more beef, than most Europeans at the time (Holmes, 1916, pp. 271-73; see Hettner 1976, p. 93). Most Colombians, however, did not eat half-a-pound of meat daily. From 1915 to 1927, it was more on the order of one to one-and-a-half ounces of meat per day on a per capita basis (Departamento de Contraloría, 1930, p. 459). This discrepancy between daily rations that were significantly higher than the national per capita rate of consumption probably stems, in good part, from the temporary and seasonal nature of much work. It is possible that many Colombians obtained much of their meat in the form of rations while working for others.6 Therefore, even if the average Colombian did not consume large quantities of meat, many did have at least periodic access to it. By the turn of the twentieth century, such recurring consumption helped beef to become a fixture -even if sometimes more symbolic than real- in the national diet and imagination.

There were, of course, plenty of variations in the development of this tradition of beef. If work-rations were an important source of meat for many peasants, this probably reinforced differentiated consumption patterns by gender and age. (Although the employment of women and children in such jobs as the coffee harvest possibly did a good deal to include them in the circuits of meat consumption.) Regional differences also mattered. The more dynamic regions, such as Antioquia, could afford to provide better rations than stagnant ones, such as Boyacá. Lowland residents also appear to have eaten more meat than highlanders, at least until the 1930s or 40s (Hettner, 1976, p. 219; Departamento de Contraloría, 1930, pp. 453459; Durán, 1882; Varela, 1952, p. 114). For some groups, therefore, the beef tradition developed quite early; for others it solidified relatively late. Still others, such as the descendants of slaves, might have seen their consumption levels fall over the 19th and into the twentieth century (see Taussig, 1977, p. 403).

But in general, beef and meat acquired both symbolic and real importance in the Colombian diet. Colombians of all classes have a hard time considering that they have had a proper meal without at least a small piece of meat. Those who subsist principally on carbohydrates do not consider themselves mainly vegetarian, but as meat-eaters who are forced to go without. The centrality of meat is the reason why even poor Colombians spend a large percentage of their income on beef (Argüelles, 1949, p. 49; Dirección Nacional de Estadística, 1948, p. 41; González, 1969, p. 45; Guarín, this issue). And it explains why the price of beef has periodically become an issue of key political importance.7

What is still not clear, however, is why beef predominated over other meats. Some scholars have argued that beef has stood at the pinnacle of the food hierarchy throughout much of Western civilization (Twigg, 1979; Fiddes, 1991; Adams, 1990; see also Beardsworth and Keil, 1997, pp. 209217). Could it be that the Colombian (and Latin American) tradition of beef is rooted in such a larger cultural complex? Even though hogs multiplied more rapidly than cattle in the early colonial period, did people, when given the chance, deliberately choose beef? There is some evidence of an historic hierarchy of meats in Colombia. Inns and steamboats in the nineteenth century did not serve fish because it was considered too cheap (Holton, 1967, p. 51).8 Hettner (1976, p. 110) even remarked that in late-nineteenth- century Bogotá, "pork is generally relegated to feed the lower classes". There might also have been some wariness about pork due to hygienic concerns (Littman, 1965). We must not assume, however, that beef was always the "elite" meat. In colonial Mexico City, with its heavy Spanish influence, mutton enjoyed this role; beef was cheaper and more plebeian (Pilcher, 2006, pp. 9, 19, 21; for Ecuador, see Patiño, 2005, p. 27). In the mid-seventeenth century, the governor of Cartagena removed the tax on beef "because it is the meat of the poor," but increased that on pork by 200 percent (Patiño, 2005, p. 27). Colonial mine owners in Colombia rewarded their administrators with ham (West, 1952, p. 116). Pork has been considered a meat for special occasions: its consumption doubles during the end-of- the- year festivities (Restrepo, 1988, p. 98; Mollien, 1992, p. 222).9 Since at least the mid-twentieth century, it has been well-to-do Colombians who, proportionally, have eaten the most pork (González, 1969, p. 41). It is not clear, therefore, that some deep cultural preference for beef can explain its predominance (see Orlove, 1997).

As I will argue in the rest of this article, there are a variety of reasons that converged to make beef the principal meat in Colombia. What I want to emphasize here is the role of tradition. From early on in some places, and certainly by the end of the nineteenth century in much of the country, meat had become a key part of a 'proper' diet. And since beef was the most-consumed meat, a culinary tradition developed around it. People from all classes, regions, and races acquired a preference for beef and created a repertoire of ways to prepare it. They likewise failed to develop a wide range of pork-based dishes, as a comparison between Mexican and Colombian cookbooks will show. Pork, therefore, had less culinary appeal. As the manager of one hog farm remarked, "people do not have the custom of eating pork" (Gómez Cuéllar, 1909, p. 196).

Too much emphasis on tradition, however, leaves little room for change (Mennell, 1996, pp.4-6). Since the mid-nineteenth century, there have been shifts in tastes and culinary practices: from salted or dried to fresh beef; from boiled to pan-fried; the slow spread of new cuts; the gradual diffusion of dishes once restricted to elites; the phenomenal growth of chicken consumption in recent years. But many of these are variations on a theme; the basic structure of the cuisine remains very similar to what it was a century or more ago: a bit of meat amidst a plethora of starches.10

Additionally, taste may play a role beyond the significance of tradition: what I (sarcastically) call the culinary determinism of beans. In many cuisines around the world, there is a propensity to pair pork and beans: feijoada (Brazil), cassoulet (southwestern France), split-pea soup (northern Europe),fabada (Asturias, Spain), pork-and-beans (U.S.), frisoles (Antioquia, Colombia). Could it be that Colombians eat little pork partly because they are not big bean eaters? Mexicans and Brazilians, for example, eat three to four times more beans than Colombians, and they eat proportionally more pork (FAOSTAT, 2007). In Colombia, the region that consumes the most beans -Antioquia- is also one of the biggest consumers of pork (Varela, 1952, p. 117; Restrepo, 1988, p. 97). It is plausible that Colombia developed such a strong tradition of beef partly because of the availability of a wide variety of other starches besides beans -potatoes, yucca, plantain, among many others- all of which do well cooked in beef -rather than pork- flavored water. This pork-bean link is not entirely consistent throughout Latin America. Chileans, for example, eat a fair amount of pork but few beans; and Nicaraguans eat lots of beans but little pork (FAOSTAT, 2007). By themselves, beans are not a determinant. Nonetheless, this idea does suggest the variety of possible factors at play behind culinary traditions and consumption patterns.

The comparative advantage of beef

While tradition and beans probably played some role in the formation of meat consumption patterns in Colombia, there is a simpler and more fundamental factor: price. Historically, beef has been significantly cheaper than pork. While the price data I have gathered so far is scattered, it does show a consistent, and often substantial, premium paid for pork. In Bogotá, between 1953 and 1965, pork was almost 20 percent more expensive than beef. In general, however, the difference was upwards of 40 percent and sometimes it was even higher (see Figure 3). Back in the eighteenth century, pork was four times the price of beef (Vargas, 1944, p. 90).11 Given the substantial price elasticity of meat consumption in Colombia, much of the historic preference for beef is likely just a reflection of the higher cost of the alternatives (Galvis, 2000). After all, if pork costs 40 percent more than beef, the decision by a poor family of which meat to buy does not seem very difficult. For this reason, Gómez Rueda (1936, p. 499), head of the government's Department of Livestock, stated that "if the price [of pork] were lower than it currently is, which would allow it to compete with beef, its consumption would increase considerably".

A variety of other circumstantial evidence also points to the importance of price. At the beginning of the twentieth century, a number of large hog farmers from the Sabana de Bogotá noted that one of the obstacles their industry faced was the public's penchant for beef rather than pork. But they also realized that it would be difficult to increase pork consumption so long as it remained more expensive (Gómez Cuéllar, 1909). Second, studies also show that Colombians eat more pork when they have more disposable income (González, 1969, p. 41). Third, the one principal exception to the price premium for pork was in the Sinú Valley from the 1930s to the 1950s. There, hog raising expanded after the government restricted lard imports. Instead of shipping live hogs to the interior of the country, butchers slaughtered them locally and tins of lard were sent inland. Without a way to transport the meat to other markets, it had to be consumed quickly in the region. As a result, pork became cheap enough here to be "the meat of the poor."12 Finally, at least since the 1960s, the price difference between pork and beef in Mexico and Brazil has been smaller than in Colombia, which may help explain why these two countries consume more pork (FAOSTAT, 2005).

We should be careful not to place too much emphasis on price alone, however. In Colombia, pork consumption sometimes has a quasi U-shaped curve in which people from poorer and wealthier groups consume proportionally more pork than those in the middle (Argüelles, 1949, p. 47; Pérez, 1915; Dirección Nacional de Estadística, 1948). This seeming paradox can be explained only if we pay attention to the characteristics of the meat not just its cost. Proportionally, wealthier people eat more pork because they can afford it. Poorer people buy more pork because "although it is generally more expensive, it is more flavorful and can be stretched further, that is, it enables a greater consumption of vegetables and bread" (Pérez, 1915, p. 105). In other words, the poor sometimes bought pork because of its property as a flavoring agent rather than to eat meat per se.13

Nonetheless, if price does play a key role in determining meat consumption patterns, why has beef been historically cheaper than pork? Hogs are generally considered to be more productive than cattle: they convert feed into flesh more efficiently; they are more prolific; they grow and fatten faster; and they consume waste products (not only farm surplus but inferior agricultural products with little value, waste from agricultural processing, and kitchen scraps). Additionally, hogs can forage for themselves; and some creole breeds (e.g., the zungo-costeño) did well on pasture grasses and legumes (Dirección Nacional de Estadística, 1952, p. 17; Gómez Cuéllar, 1909; Ospina, 1913, p. 237; Ospina, 1940; Gade, 2000, p. 537; Cronon, 1991, pp. 225-226). The advantages of raising hogs were such that most peasant households tried to keep at least a few (CIAT, 1972, p. 92; Paris, 1946, pp. 240242; Léonet al., 1975, p. 2). Given the low opportunity-cost of many hogs, why would pork be more expensive than beef?

The traditional answer is that Colombia, and indeed much of Latin America, has had a comparative advantage in natural grasslands. Ernst-Ludwig Littman (1965, p. 7), for example, noted that beef remained cheaper than pork even when the price of grains was favorable for raising hogs:

From the biological point of view, this is a contradiction, since the efficiency of converting forage into meat is higher in hogs than cattle. The explanation is found in the existence of vast extensions of natural grasses in Colombia just as in Argentina, which can be used for extensive cattle production without large investments.... Ample land resources and the availability of labor give a decisive advantage to cattle raising at the cost of hog farming.

Likewise, Lowell Jarvis (1986, p. 10) stated that in Latin America the "abundant supply [of cattle] from low-cost pastoral resources has led to a tradition of high beef consumption by all levels of the population". Cheap grass, principally from natural grasslands, enabled Latin American cattle to out-compete hogs.

In Colombia, however, this argument runs into some problems. Here, cheap savanna land has been less critical to the national cattle industry than perhaps elsewhere in Latin America. Colombia's quintessential grasslands, the Llanos Orientales, were not that significant nationally until well into the twentieth century (García, 2003; Rausch, 1993). The centerof Colombian ranching for the last century or so has been the Caribbean coast and Antioquia. Here, the predominate forage has not been from natural savannas but from "artificial" or planted pastures. While cattle mainly grazed on natural grasslands up to the mid-nineteenth century, since then the big expansion of ranching has largely come at the expense of the country's lowland forests. This transformation of forest into pasture, however, was often difficult, risky and expensive: grass was not cheap for the taking (Van Ausdal, MS).

But despite the cost and effort of developing pastures, grass was still cheaper than corn, which was often used to fatten hogs. Much of the price premium for pork can be traced back to the high cost of feed. Throughout the twentieth century, industry observers repeated the refrain: "[W]ithout cheap feed is it impossible to get cheap lard [and pork]" (Gómez Rueda, 1936, p. 499; see also Gómez Cuéllar, 1909, pp. 196, 200, 202, 203; Ospina, 1940, p. 100; Littman, 1965, p. 7; CIAT, 1972, pp. 9394; León etal., 1975, p. 18).14

Trying to pinpoint the cost differences between producing grass and corn, or cattle and hogs, is not straightforward, however. Data, especially before 1950, is difficult to find, scattered geographically and temporally, and is not always easily comparable. One way to try to address the comparability problem is to calculate production costs in terms of the labor required to fatten hogs and cattle. Based on data from Antioquia in the 1950s, I calculate that it took roughly six or seven days of labor to produce the corn necessary to fatten one hog.15 By contrast, in the Bajo Cauca in the early 1920s, it took only four days of labor to fatten a steer.16 Obviously, this comparison does not tell the full story, but it does suggest that one of the problems faced by the Colombian hog industry was the amount of labor required to produce feed. One of the main advantages of raising cattle rather than hogs was that the substantial initial cost of buying or developing pasture land could be amortized over a relatively long period of time; by contrast, the land preparation and weeding costs needed to grow corn were a constant and heavy burden. A quick comparison with the United States provides some perspective on the amount of effort that went into farming corn in Colombia. There was some difference in the yield per hectare: in the U.S., up to 1940, the average was 1,600 kilograms; in Antioquia, in 1955, the estimate was 1,500 kilograms (U.S. Dept. of Commerce, 1975, Series K 445-485; Caja de Crédito Agrario Industrial y Minero, 1955, p. 15). But a key part of the difference was the amount of time required to produce that hectare of corn. In the U.S., the average number of labor-hours it took a farmer to produce 1,600 kilograms of corn had dropped from 163 in the mid-nineteenth century to 64 in 1940 (U.S. Dept. of Commerce, 1975, Series K 445485). By contrast, it still took Antioqueño farmers over 400 hours to produce the same amount of grain in the 1950s (Caja de Crédito Agrario Industrial y Minero, 1955, p. 15; see alsoCurrie, 1966, p. 174; Céspedes, 1979; Posada, 1952, p. 101).

The substantial labor required to grow corn, sometimes for only mediocre yields, made it expensive.17 M. T. Dawe (1915, p. 525), British agricultural advisor to the Colombian government in the late 1910s, was shocked by the high price of corn, which sold for four times what it did in east and southern Africa.18 Fifty years later, Littman (1965, p. 1) reiterated that "[t]he ratio between the price of hogs and grains (corn, barley) or root crops (potatoes) was unfavorable to the development of intensive pork production in Colombia." The high cost of corn, therefore, stood in the way of greater pork consumption. More than just the availability of cheap, natural grasslands, much of the comparative advantage of beef lay in the low productivity of the country's agriculture.19

But why did the cost of corn make pork more expensive than beef? After all, hogs can grow and fatten on other types of feed besides corn and other costly crops. They do well, for example, on waste products from the farm and kitchen, and can forage for themselves. Around 1940, Kathryn Wylie (1942, p. 127) noted that farmers "allowed [their hogs] to root for themselves" and fed them little corn (see also Havens, 1965, pp. 130-131). Even into the 1980s, most hogs in Colombia were raised by peasants or small-scale farmers who relied principally on feed with limited or no market value (Restrepo, 1988). It is not obvious, therefore, that the price of grain would be so critical to the hog industry.

Nonetheless, numerous contemporary observers and later historians have remarked on the importance of corn as hog feed, especially for fattening. A corn-hog complex characterized a good deal of Antioqueño colonization, for example: colonos relied on hogs to increase the value of frontier corn surpluses and move them to market (Parsons, 1968, pp. 73, 7879, 89; Brew, 2000, pp. 190192; Poveda, 1979, pp. 110111; see also Restrepo, 1988; COINCO, 1988). Tulio Ospina (1913, p. 238) claimed that in Antioquia "corn is the principal feed during the fattening stage." In the late-nineteenth century, Camacho Roldán (1946, pp. 183, 195) estimated that about half of the hogs slaughtered in Colombia (some 300,000 to 400,000) were fattened on corn, "each one of which consumes between two and four hundred pounds of grain"20. According to the manager of a large hog farm near Bogotá at the beginning of the twentieth century, corn or other grains and tubers (barley, fava beans, potatoes, etc.) were too expensive to be used at any other stage except fattening (Gómez Cuéllar, 1909, p. 196). The 300 to 400 percent difference between the price of thin and fat hogs likely rested on the low opportunity-costs of breeding pigs and the importance of corn to fatten them.21 Wylie, therefore, was probably correct to state that, overall, hogs ate little corn. Farmers generally allowed their hogs to roam freely, feeding on pasture grasses and in fallow fields or forests until the age of 10 to 12 months. Afterwards, however, enough hogs did fatten on corn (and other agricultural products) for it to become an important determinant in the price of pork and lard.

Moving hogs to market likely reinforced the use of corn to fatten them for slaughter. If they walk much without being fed, hogs will burn off their stores of fat and profit. This circumscribed the geographic area in which they could be profitably fattened for a particular market.22 Hogs from outside this area had to be fattened locally. The wide "hog-shed" of larger markets thus helped sustain the inter-regional movement of animals and the numbers that had to be fattened on corn or similar products. When frontier lands were relatively close to major markets, hogs were a convenient way to transform surplus corn (or other crop) into a mobile and marketable product. Once the distance became too great, however, raising fat hogs ceased to be profitable (COINCO, 1988). Similarly, extensive hog raising where land was cheap, whether by foraging, scavenging, or feeding on pasture grasses and legumes, was mostly limited to thin animals. Fat hogs needed a relatively easy way to get to market or had to be slaughtered locally. This is why hog farmers in the Sinú Valley -the largest hog-producing region in the 1930s- slaughtered the bulk of their own animals. It was more profitable to sell tins of lard to the interior of the country, even though this undercut the price of pork locally, than send live hogs.

Additionally, the high cost of corn (and other feed) also helped raise the price of pork by limiting the overall pig population. Because grains were expensive, hogs were principally a backyard activity that turned waste products into cash and took advantage of female and child labor. Since each peasant household could only generate so much waste, this limited the number of hogs they could profitably raise. As a result, cattle far outnumbered hogs.

In 1960, there was only one pig in Colombia for every five head of cattle (DANE, 1964, pp. 5354). A team of livestock experts from the United Nations (1962, p. 5) found that there was good demand for pork in the 1950s, but that its "consumption [was] severely restricted by supply difficulties and high prices". Small hog populations likely helped boost prices.

Four other factors further limited hog supplies and sustained prices. First, the settlement of the agrarian frontier and the spread of pasturelands eventually undercut hog raising. Corn yields tended to be high in lands recently cleared of old-growth forest, and hogs were a convenient way to transport surpluses to market. Areas of colonization, therefore, were often important hog producers. The bonanza years were short-lived, however. And as falling corn yields pushed the corn-hog complex increasingly further from markets, it became harder to profitably use hogs to turn surpluses into mobile commodities (Parsons, 1968, p. 89). Furthermore, the introduction of African pasture grasses in the mid-nineteenth century helped changed the dynamics of pasture formation. These quick- growing and livestock-resistant grasses -pará (Brachiaria mutica) and guinea (Panicum maximum)- helped prevent forest re-growth in recently cleared areas by rapidly forming a dense mat-like ground cover (Rivas, 1983, p. 36; Van Ausdal, MS; also see Parsons, 1972). They encouraged ranchers to develop new pastures out of the forest and farmers to plant grass in fallow fields. As a result, the once forested landscape -or patchwork of forest, fallow, and field- became increasingly dominated by grass. The development of new pastures initially stimulated corn production, which was used to loosen the soil before planting grass and help cover expenses. In the long run, however, the spread of permanent pastures stimulated cattle ranching at the expense of hogs. There is some scattered evidence to suggest that Colombians, at least in some regions, consumed more pork when there was more forest and less grass. In the mid -to late- nineteenth century, pork consumption rates appear to have been higher in parts of Old Bolívar than they would be in the twentieth century.23 Pedro Nel Ospina could not find a market for his cattle in Ituango (Antioquia) in the early-twentieth century because the peasants of this frontier zone raised too many pigs (APNOyC, 200, p. 452). Pork consumption, though never very strong, may have slowly tapered off as colonos and cattle ranchers cleared the forests and planted grass (see Figure 1).

Second, the lack of elite interest in raising hogs limited their numbers. This reluctance may have stemmed from a degree of "repugnance" for the activity (Gómez Cuéllar, 1909, p. 193). But there were some practical reasons as well. For example, there were greater economies of scale in raising cattle than extensively-raised hogs (Poveda, 1979, p. 110; see also Van Ausdal, forthcoming). Many also thought that intensive hog raising was not worth the effort. Most dairy farmers on the Sabana de Bogotá preferred to throw or give away their leftover whey from cheese-making rather than use it to raise pigs (Gómez Cuéllar, 1909, p. 193). For hacendados without a ready supply of waste products that they could use for feed, raising hogs would require them to become farmers. Although the landed elite thought of themselves as agricultores, farming was something that, outside of a few products, many were unwilling to do: the risks of climate, pests, and overproduction were too great (Camacho Roldán, 1976, p. 125; Brew, 2000, pp. 210212; Reinhardt, 1988; Van Ausdal, MS). Also, there were few economies of scale in farming staples until the spread of mechanization in the 1950s.24 As a result, the landed elite generally left hog raising to peasants, a division of labor that the 1960 agriculture and livestock census clearly shows (see Figure 4).

A third factor that limited hog raising was the difficulty of generating low-cost feed from the waste of food processing industries. Colombian hog boosters encouraged entrepreneurs to take advantage of cheap by-products such as skim milk and whey from dairies, bran from millers, mash from breweries, oil seed cakes from vegetable oil mills, and slaughterhouse waste (Gómez Cuéllar, 1909; Medina, 1936, p. 444; Bernal, 1937; Ospina, 1940). While there were some steps in this direction, even into the second half of the twentieth century little progress had been made (León et al., 1975; Restrepo, 1988). One reason was the late urbanization of the country. Small urban markets, and low purchasing power more generally, limited the amount of available by-products. The geographic dispersion of waste material further limited the economies of scale that could have turned them into low-cost sources of feed. For example, without a system of cold chains with which to centralize slaughtering, every municipality had its own slaughterhouse. Even in the second half of the twentieth century, many of these were too small to warrant processing their waste (United Nations, 1962, pp. 26-27). Even where there was a high degree of concentration, such as the vegetable oil industry in Barranquilla, high transportation costs discouraged the use of cottonseed cake as hog feed.

Finally, while traditional methods of 'extensive' hog rearing did not limit their numbers, they did limit the amount of meat that existing stocks produced. Even in the second half of the twentieth century, most Colombian hogs were hardy, self -reliant, disease- resistant creole breeds that had adapted well to local environments. But compared to improved breeds, they grew and reproduced slowly, and yielded less meat and fat (León et al., 1975, p. 16; Peñarete, 1958, p. 216; Ospina, 1913, p. 237). Furthermore, many hogs raised in this fashion received inadequate diets, which slowed their growth even more, lowered the speed at which they reproduced, and increased their mortality rates (Littman, 1965, 3; León et al., 1975, pp. 10, 32; CIAT, 1972, 9293; Bernal, 1937, p. 936; Gómez Rueda, 1936, p. 554). Before 1950, boosters claimed that it was possible to raise hogs in six to ten months and fatten them in two (Bernal, 1937, p. 925; Ospina, 1940, pp. 40-41). Most Colombian hogs, however, were not raised under 'ideal' conditions. Even in the early 1970s, it could take 15 to 18 months before they were ready for slaughter (CIAT, 1972, p. 92; León et al., 1975, p. 10; see also Ospina, 1913, p. 237; Bernal, 1937, p. 936; Peñarete, 1958, p. 216). Slaughtering hogs at this late age meant that they did not produce meat much more efficiently than cattle.25

The politics of pork

In the previous section, I argue that the high price of pork relative to beef limited its consumption. Pork was expensive because of the high cost of corn, used to fatten hogs, as well as a small pig population. These immediate causes, in turn, were rooted in the low productivity of Colombian agriculture, a small national market, the slow process of industrialization, elite disinterest, and the advantages of pasture and cattle. But just how 'natural' was the comparative advantage of beef? Was it primarily an economic issue? Or did politics, power, and policy decisions also have an impact? In this section, I look at the politics behind meat consumption in two different ways.26 First, I examine how the political power of ranchers and their monopolization of much of the country's land negatively influenced hog raising. Second, I explore how the politics of lard imports helped to undermine pork consumption.

Two salient characteristics of the Colombian countryside have long been the inequitable land tenure structure and the vast majority of 'agricultural' land dedicated to raising cattle. Could the monopolization of land by ranchers be responsible for the country's beef-heavy diet? There are two ways this monopolization might have influenced meat consumption patterns. On the one hand, ranchers may have boosted the competitiveness of beef by raising cattle on the best agricultural land in the country. In so doing, they benefited from better pastures and more productive cattle operations. But more importantly, their control of the flat, fertile valley floors forced peasant agriculture onto more marginal hillsides, lowering its productivity and raising food (and feed) prices. This 'irrational' distribution of agricultural and pasture lands may have helped give beef an edge over pork (IBRD, 1956, p. 54; Currie, 1950). On the other hand, it is possible that the general monopolization of land also contributed to the competitiveness of cattle. One consequence of this monopolization was a land-hungry peasantry that was willing to clear forests and plant pasture in exchange for temporary access to land. In such arrangements, ranchers provided peasants with patches of forested land to farm for a few years so long as they returned it under grass.27 These land-for-pasture exchanges aided the expansion of ranching and ultimately may have had some effect on the price of beef. Another consequence of this monopolization was to push peasants out to the agrarian frontier where they would undertake the hard labor of settling the forest. Ranchers later followed them to consolidate the lands that they had cleared (Fals Borda, 1976, 2002, pp. 162164; Negrete and Garabito, 1985; Reyes, 1978). Beef might have also benefited from the labor of these peasant colonizers through cheap land sales and the usurpation of developed plots. Lastly, the unequal land tenure structure squeezed the peasantry onto a small land base. Since peasants raised the bulk of the hogs in the country, the reduced size of their farms limited the number that each family was capable of raising and, therefore, the overall pig population.

Although it is likely that the inequitable distribution of land in Colombia negatively influenced hog raising, we should be careful not to overstate its impact. Any substantial expansion of hog raising would likely have depended on obtaining a cheap source of feed. Even though the peasantry might have been able to raise more hogs if they had greater access to land, there still remained the problem of fattening them for market. While they could have also grown more corn, without some way to substantially increase the productivity of their labor, hog and pork prices would have remained high. Additionally, without high-protein feed supplements, peasant hogs were not much more efficient than cattle at producing meat. And although a good number of ranchers profited from land-for-pasture exchanges or by cheaply 'buying' peasant clearings, the cattle industry did not depend on such practices (Van Ausdal, MS). There are limits to how much land usurpation subsidized the price of beef.

The second kind of political influence I want to address revolves around the question of trade and the place of lard in the Colombian diet. In 1944, the newspaper, Diario de la Costa, blamed the 'demise' of the coastal hog-raising industry on the 1936 trade treaty between Colombia and the United States: a 50 percent drop in the tariff on lard, it argued, unleashed a wave of U.S. imports that drove peasant hog producers out of business.28 Up to the mid- twentieth century, lard (along with tallow) was the most important source of cooking fat in Colombia and a key part of the hog industry.29 Did freer trade in lard undermine Colombian hog raising and, by consequence, pork consumption?

Lard imports did not begin in 1936. Camacho Roldán (1946, p. 130) suggested that they started sometime in the mid-nineteenth century, causing the price of lard in Bogotá to fall from $20 pesos per arroba (25 metric pounds) to $1. By 1909, if not earlier, Colombia imported roughly half the lard it consumed from the United States (Gómez Cuéllar, 1909, p. 4; Bell, 1921). A sharp reduction of lard imports during WWI stimulated the domestic industry.

Yet local supplies could not keep pace with growing demand, and by the end of the 1920s Colombia was again importing about half of the lard it consumed.30 In an effort to reduce its dependence on U.S. lard, the government raised the import duty on lard by 500 percent in 1931. This measure considerably slowed imports but did not stop them. The following year, therefore, the government promulgated a sanitary regulation that effectively put an end to the trade.31 Lard was an important component of the 1936 trade treaty between the U.S. and Colombia. However, while the treaty reduced the tariff by 50 percent, it did not address the sanitary restrictions. U.S. lard remained blocked from the Colombian market except when cooking-oil shortages during WWII prompted the government to temporarily lift the restriction.32 The 1936 trade treaty, therefore, did not undermine Colombian hog producers. Nonetheless, the much longer history of lard imports prior to 1930 probably did discourage production by keeping a lid on prices (Camacho Roldán, 1973, p. 197; Restrepo Plata, 1912, p. 400; Díaz, 1996, p. 329). (Though whether or not the country could have afforded much higher lard prices, without drastically reducing its consumption, is another question.)

Ironically, the protectionism of the early-1930s eventually helped undermine hog raising and pork consumption. Despite the government's interest in reducing lard imports, it is doubtful that peasant hog-farmers could have effectively lobbied the government for protective trade policies. In fact, the government designed the measures to protect the nascent vegetable oil industry. By limiting lard imports, and reducing the duty on copra, the primary raw material in vegetable shortening, officials helped domestic manufacturers lower their production costs and grab a larger market share. Hog producers initially benefited from the measures. In the long run, however, they lost out as vegetable shortening (and eventually oil) displaced lard as the preeminent cooking fat.33

Conclusion

So why have Colombians historically eaten so much more beef than pork? The principal reason, I argue, is that pork has long been more expensive than beef; and that this price difference is rooted in the low productivity of Colombian agriculture. But the road to understanding consumption patterns is rarely straight and short. In this case, a variety of factors, in addition to price, converged to make beef -until recently- the king of meats in Colombia: the development of a taste for and tradition of beef; the culinary influence of other staples; a receding agrarian frontier; the lack of elite interest in hog raising; land tenure patterns; the difficulty of developing by- product industries; a long history of cheap imports; the "modernization" of cooking fats. Although consumption studies have recently begun to emphasize the ideological and contested nature of food and diet, my focus here has been largely material: on what has influenced price and supply rather than the cultural politics of demand. Food is not just a matter of sustenance; a range of symbolic, cultural and political factors shape what and how we eat. Nonetheless, in the case of meat consumption in Colombia, the high cost of (corn and) pork did much to secure the long-held predominance of beef.


Comentarios

1 The culprit, of course, was chicken. For the fascinating yet dis-turbing story of the rise of modern chicken production, see Molina (2002), Boyd and Watts (1997), and Striffler (2005).

2 Tropaeoleum tuberosum.

3 AHC, Gobernación, Justicia (1905-1933), Folder 25, "...Marcial González... y Juan Grice han celebrado el siguiente contrato: 1905-6".

4 Martínez, 1990, pp. 91-92; AGN, República, Carnicerías Oficiales (Volume I), pp. 23-24, 27.

5 For mid-twentieth-century consumption statistics, see Gómez Durán (1939); Parsons (1968, p. 119); García (1978, pp. 266- 289); Argüelles (1949); Bejarano (1941, pp. 133-135); Muñoz and Hurtado (1950); Dirección Nacional de Estadística (1948); AOFB, Cereté-Sindicato-Liga de Trabajadores, "Sistemas de alimentación en la región de Sabanas".

6 It is possible that meat served as an incentive to attract rural laborers, especially where they were scarce.

7 For example, see NARA, Record Group (RG) 166 (1942-1945), Colombia, Box 178, Anne Sundelin Floyd, "Summary of current meat price controversy, Bogotá, Colombia," May 23, 1945.

8 In the early 1820s, Hamilton (1993, p. 317) also noted that the Medical Board of Buga, in the Cauca Valley, limited the amount of fish that could be sold in the city in order to prevent a reduction in beef and mutton consumption.

9 In the colonial era, pork was also considered to be good for one's health (Saldarriaga, 2006).

10 The paucity of immigration into Colombia is one possible reason for the limits of change: without the introduction of new tastes, ingredients and methods of food preparation, cooks tend to stick with what they know.

11 Vargas gave prices for a large hog in 1739 and 1791. The cost difference assumes that his large hog yielded 100 pounds of meat and fat. In the mid-twentieth century, the average yield in meat, fat, and bone was estimated to be 76.5 pounds (Dávila, 1948, p. 54).

12 NARA, RG 84, Consulate Records, Colombia, Cartagena (Securi-ty Segregated, 1943), Box 14, "Economic Survey of the Cartagena, Colombia Consular District," R. Kenneth Oakley, Nov. 10, 1943.

13 It should be noted, however, that the price differential in Bar-ranquilla at this time was not as large as in other parts of the country. It is likely that, once it surpassed a certain price, it was no longer worth buying pork.

14 In the early 1970s, a development project found that penned hogs, fed improved diets, gained weight three times faster and with three times less feed, than "traditionally" raised animals. But because of the high cost of 'improved' feed, even with such productivity gains, profit margins remained razor thin while the degree of risk greatly increased. Needless to say, the targeted peasants did not adopt most of the project's recommendations (CIAT, 1972).

15 The Caja de Crédito Agrario, Industrial y Minero (1955) estimated that it cost $383 to produce and market one hectare of corn in Antioquia. This was equivalent to over 100 days of labor in terms of prevailing wages. The average yield from this hect are was 1,500 kilograms of corn. If we consider only the actual labor costs of land preparation, planting, and weeding -and ignore land, harvesting, processing, marketing, and administrative costs- it took about 44 days to grow one hectare of corn. One day's labor, therefore, produced about 34 kilograms of corn. His-torical observers suggest that it took between 200 and 250 kilos of corn, and two months, to fatten a hog, doubling its weight from roughly 50 to 100 kilograms (Ospina, 1940; Bernal, 1937).

16 Based on the 1922 estimate that it cost between $1,000 and $1,200 per month to maintain 2,000 hectares of artificial pastures in the Bajo Cauca, including fence repair, animal care, and salt. Wages were between 50¢ to 60¢ per day, and the pastures had a stocking rate of two head per hectare (APNOyC, Correspondencia 1917-1936, Feb. 1, 1922).

17 Added to this were production difficulties, storage losses, and high marketing costs (Dawe, 1915; Guerra, 1966; Ruiz de Lon-doño and Pinstrup-Anderson, 1975).

18 In the late-nineteenth century, the price of corn appears to have been about twice that in the U.S. (Camacho Roldán, 1976, p. 117; see also Lagoeyte, 1918, p. 377). Around 1960, according to Currie (1966, p. 173), the difference had risen to 180 percent.

19 By low productivity I mean that crop yields were not very large in terms of inputs of land, labor, and capital. In turn, this helped make agricultural products expensive. Limited capital inputs (e.g., fertilizer), partly the result of an historic urban bias in agri cultural policy, were one cause of low yields per unit of land and labor. (My thanks to one of the anonymous reviewers for high-lighting this point.) Colombian agriculture faced additional chal-lenges as well. For instance, the rugged topography of much of the country's farmland made mechanization difficult. The highcost of inputs also undercut a good deal of the increased productivity gains of mechanized agriculture (see Céspedes, 1979, Tabla 15).

20 Alejandro López (1915, p. 28) stated that in Antioquia, 100,000 hogs were fattened on about 200 kilograms of corn each. See also Monsalve (1929, p.148), who noted the maxim, "purchased corn does not fatten"; Ospina, 1940; Bernal, 1937.

21 Guerrero, 1881; APNOyC, Hojas Sueltas, Feria de Ganado de Medellín el 8 de agosto de 1934; NARA, RG 166, 1946-1949, Colombia, Box 623, "Annual Livestock and Meat Report," March 11, 1949.

22 Walsh (1977, p. 707) thought that the proliferation of small pork-packing operations meant that most farmers in the U.S. Midwest during the early -and mid- nineteenth century did not send their hogs great distances to be slaughtered. For longer trips they tended to take advantage of canals and later railroads. See also Cronon (1991, pp. 225-227).

23 Gaceta de Bolívar, no. 443, Sept. 9, 1866, p. 3; Gaceta de Bolívar, no. 454, Nov. 4, 1866, pp.1-2; Gaceta de Bolívar, no. 551, March 29, 1868, p. 7; Gaceta de Bolívar, no. 646, Oct. 3, 1869; Gaceta de Bolívar, no. 702, July 31, 1870, pp. 299-303. Old Bolívar in-cludes the contemporary departments of Bolívar, Atlántico, Sucre, and Córdoba.

24 The landed elite, therefore, tended to concentrate on products for which the markets were stronger (exports) or where they did not compete to the same degree with peasant production (cattle, sugarcane, wheat), and on sharecropping or other forms of land rental.

25 In the 1950s, the yield of pork per head of stock in the national herd was not much higher than beef: 34.2 kilograms versus 30.5 for cattle (United Nations, 1962, p. 20).

26 For reasons of space, I do not address how the government sup- ported the cattle industry -through research and extension work, subsidies, credit, and other programs- but did little to assist hog farmers. While such policies helped ranching expand geographi-cally, they also contributed to the slow improvement of ranching productivity. While there are also some indications that the productivity of hog raising improved over the twentieth century, such gains probably lagged behind those of the cattle industry. This could be another way that beef maintained its competitive edge over pork.

27 Fals Borda, 1976; 2002, p. 124B; NARA, RG 166, 1942-45, Colombia, Box 178, "Cattle raising and related industries in the Department of Bolívar, Colombia," R. Kenneth Oakley, July 31, 1944.

28 NARA, RG 84, Consulate Records, Colombia, Cartagena (General, 1943-48), Box 11, "Resolutions re: Hog lard," 1944.

29 NARA, RG 166, 1942-45, Colombia, Box 175, "Lard and Vegetable Lard - Colombia," John A. Hopkins, Dec. 6, 1944.

30 NARA, RG 166, 1946-49, Colombia, Box 625, "Semi-Annual Fats and Oils Report," Kenneth Wernimont and Jon G. Fossett, Nov. 12, 1948.

31 Ibid.

32 NARA, RG 166, 1942-45, Colombia, Box 177, "Colombian Dis-crimination Against Hog Lard," March 3, 1945; NARA, RG 84, Consulate Records, Colombia, Cartagena (Security Segregated, 1943), Box 14, "Economic Survey of the Cartagena, Colombia Consular District," R. Kenneth Oakley, Nov. 10, 1943.

33 By 1960, lard comprised only about 15 percent of the national fat and oil market, down from around 75 percent during the early-1940s: see Ministerio de Agricultura (1968, p. 4); NARA, RG 166, 1942-45, Colombia, Box 175, "Oilcrops and Vegetable Lard - Colombia," May 3, 1945; NARA, RG 166, 1942-45, Colombia, Box 175, "Lard and Vegetable Lard - Colombia," John A. Hopkins, Dec. 6, 1945


Archives

1. Archivo Pedro Nel Ospina y Compañía (Fundación Antioqueña de Estudios Sociales or FAES, Medellín) -APNOyC         [ Links ]

2. Archivo Orlando Fals Borda (Banco de la República library, Montería)-AOFB        [ Links ]

3. Archivo Histórico de Cartagena - AHC        [ Links ]

4. Archivo General de la Nación (Bogotá) - AGN        [ Links ]

5. National Archives and Record Administration (Washington, D.C.) - NARASource: DANE (1964).        [ Links ]

References

1. Arboleda C., H. (1905). Estadística General de la República de Colombia. Bogotá: Imprenta Nacional.        [ Links ]

2. Argüelles Vargas, F. (1952). La Alimentación de la Clase Obrera en Barranquilla. Anales de Economía y Estadística, 8(73), 44-52.        [ Links ]

3. Barsky, O. & Gelman, J. (2001). Historia del Agro Argentino: Desde la Conquista hasta Fines del Siglo XX. Buenos Aires: Grijalbo Mondadori.        [ Links ]

4. Beardsworth, A. & Keil, T. (1997). Sociology on the Menu: An Invitation to the Study of Food and Society. London: Routledge.        [ Links ]

5. Bejarano, J. (1941). Alimentación y Nutrición en Colombia. Bogotá: Editorial Cromos.        [ Links ]

6. Bell, P. L. (1921). Colombia: A Commercial and Industrial Handbook. Washington: Government Printing Office.        [ Links ]

7. Bishko, C. J. (1952). The Peninsular Background of Latin American Cattle Ranching. Hispanic American Historical Review, 32(4), 491-515.        [ Links ]

8. Boussingault, J. B. (1994). Memorias de Jean Baptiste Bous-singault. Bogotá: Comisión Preparatoria para el V Centenario del Descubrimiento de América, Instituto Colombiano de Cultura, Banco de la República.        [ Links ]

9. Boyd, W. & Watts, M. (1997). Agro-Industrial Just-in-Time:The Chicken Industry and Postwar American Capitalism. In D. Goodman & M. Watts (Eds.), Globalising Food: Agrarian Questions and Global Restructuring. London: Routledge.        [ Links ]

10. Brew, R. (2000). El Desarrollo Económico deAntioquia desde la Independencia hasta 1920. Medellín: Clío, Editorial Universidad de Antioquia.        [ Links ]

11. Brungardt, M. P. (1974). Tithe Production and Patterns of Economic Change in Central Colombia, 1764-1833. Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Dept. of History, Universityof Texas, Austin.        [ Links ]

12. Caja de Crédito Agrario Industrial y Minero (1955). Producción Nacional: Estudio sobre los Principales Aspectos del Desarrollo de la Producción Agropecuaria. Bogotá: Caja de Crédito Agrario Industrial y Minero.        [ Links ]

13. Calero, L. F. (1997). Chiefdoms Under siege: Spain's Rule and Native Adaptation in the Southern Colombian Andes, 1535-1700. Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press.        [ Links ]

14. Camacho, R., Salvador. (1946). Memorias. Bogotá: Editorial ABC.

15. Camacho Roldán, S. (1973). Notas de Viaje (Colombia y Estados Unidos de América). Bogotá: Banco de la República.        [ Links ]

16. Camacho Roldán, S. (1976). Escritos Sobre Economía y Política. Bogotá: Instituto Colombiano de Cultura.        [ Links ]

17. Cañón, J. J. (1952). Aspectos Económicos de la Ganadería en Colombia. Bogotá: Ministerio de Agricultura.        [ Links ]

18. Céspedes Ortiz, L. (1979). Diagnóstico sobre la Producción y Mercadeo de Maíz en Colombia. Bogotá: Universidad Externado de Colombia.        [ Links ]

19. CIAT. (1972). Sistemas de Producción de Ganado Porcino. Informe Anual- 1972. Cali: CIAT.        [ Links ]

20. Cooperativa de Intendencias y Comisarias (COINCO) (1988). Desarrollo de Producción Porcina en Territorios Naco-niales: Arauca, Guaviare, Caquetá. Bogotá: COINCO.

21. Cronon, W. (1991). Nature's Metropolis: Chicago and the Great West. New York: W. W. Norton.        [ Links ]

22. Crosby, A. (1972). The Columbian Exchange: Biological and Cultural Consequences of 1492. Westport, CT: Greenwood Press.        [ Links ]

23. Currie, L. (1966). Accelerating Development: the Necessity and the Means. New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company.        [ Links ]

24.Currie, L. (1950). The Basis of a Development Program for Colombia. Washington: The World Bank.        [ Links ]

25. Dawe, M. T. (1915). Relación de un Viaje de Santa Marta a Bogotá. Revista Agrícola: Órgano del Ministerio de Agricultura y Comercio, 1(8), 517-529.        [ Links ]

26. Departamento Administrativo Nacional de Estadística (DANE). (1964). Directorio Nacional de Explotaciones Agropecuario (Censo Agropecuario) 1960: Resúmen Nacional. Bogotá: DANE.        [ Links ]

27. Departamento Administrativo Nacional de Estadística (1965). Anuario de Estadística General. Tomo IV. Bogotá: DANE.        [ Links ]

28. Departamento de Contraloría (1930). Anuario de Estadístico de Colombia (XXIV). Bogotá: Imprenta Nacional.        [ Links ]

29. Departamento de Contraloría (1932). Anuario de Estadística General, Año de 1930 (XXXI). Bogotá: Imprenta Nacional.        [ Links ]

30. Dirección Nacional de Estadística (1948). Las Condiciones Económico-Sociales y el Costo de la Vida de la Clase Obrera en la Ciudad de Mariquita. Bogotá: Contraloría General.        [ Links ]

31. Dirección Nacional de Estadística. Coordinación Estadística (1952). Síntesis Geo-Económica del Departamento de Bolívar; Informe Rendido por Eduardo Acevedo Latorre. Bogotá: Imprenta Nacional.        [ Links ]

32. Dorta, E. M. (1962). Cartagena de Indias: Riquezas Ganaderas y Problemas. In Tercer Congreso Hispanoamericano de Historia. Tomo I. Cartagena: Talleres Gráficas Mogollón.        [ Links ]

33. Durán, F. (1882). Revista de Cosechas: Anapoima. El Agricultor, 4(2).        [ Links ]

34. Dávila Tello, J. V. (1949). Economía Agropecuario de Colombia, 1948. Bogotá: Ministerio de Agricultura y Ganadería, División de Economía Rural.        [ Links ]

35. El Tiempo (2007). Colombia ya Come, y de Lejos, Más Pollo que Res. El Tiempo, May 23, 1.        [ Links ]

36. Fals Borda, O. (1976). Capitalismo, Hacienda y Poblamiento: Su Desarrollo en la Costa Atlántica. Bogotá: Punta de Lanza.        [ Links ]

37. Fals Borda, O. (2002). Historia Doble de la Costa 4: Retorno a la Tierra. Bogotá: Universidad Nacional de Colombia, Banco de la República, El Áncora Editores.        [ Links ]

38. FAOSTAT (2007). Consumption - Core Consumption Data. Accessed August 31,2007, from http://faostat.fao.org/site/346/default.aspx        [ Links ]

39. FAOSTAT (2005). Data Archives - Prices - Livestock Primary. Accessed August 31,2007, from http://faostat.fao.org/site/427/default.aspx        [ Links ]

40. Fiddes, N. (1991). Meat, aNatural Symbol. London: Routledge.        [ Links ]

41. Flórez, A. (forthcoming). El Poder de la Carne: Historias de Ganaderías en la Primera Mitad del Siglo XX en Colombia. Bogotá: Universidad Javeriana.        [ Links ]

42. Gade, D. W. (2000). Hogs (Pigs). In K. Kiple & K. C. Ornelas (Eds.), Cambridge World History of Food. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.        [ Links ]

43. Galvis Aponte, L. A. (2000). La Demanda de Carnes en Colombia: Un Análisis Econométrico. Documentos de Trabajo sobre Economía Regional, 13.        [ Links ]

44. García Bustamante, M. (2003). Persistencia y Cambio en la Frontera Oriental de Colombia: el Piedemonte de Meta, 1840- 1950. Medellín: Fondo Editorial EAFIT.        [ Links ]

45. García, A. (1978). Geografía Económica de Caldas. Bogotá: Banco de la República.        [ Links ]

46. Gómez Cuéllar, R. (1909). La Industria de los Cerdos. Bogotá: Imprenta de la Luz.        [ Links ]

47. Gómez Rueda, M. (1936). Consideraciones sobre el Estado Actual de la Ganadería en los Distintos Climas de Colombia, y Medios para Mejorarla. Revista Nacional de Agricultura, 386, 481-513.        [ Links ]

48. González Corredor, H. (1969). Beneficio y Distribución de Carnes de Res y Cerdo en la Ciudad de Cali (Proyecto de Mercadeo Integrado Urbano Rural del Valle: Informe Técnico No. 13). Cali: Corporación Autónoma Regional del Cauca.        [ Links ]

49. Guerra E, G. A. (1966). Economic Aspects for Corn and Milo in Colombia. Medellín: Sección de Economía Agrícola y Extensión Forestal, Facultad de Agronomía e Instituto Forestal, Universidad Nacional de Colombia.        [ Links ]

50. Guerrero, M. (1881). Revista de Cosechas: de Cali. El Agricultor, 2(20), 362-363.        [ Links ]

51. Guzmán Durán, A. (1939). Necesidad de Alimentarse Bien. Revista Nacional de Agricultura, 34(423), 684-696.        [ Links ]

52. Hamilton, J. P. (1993). Viajes por el Interior de las Provincias de Colombia. Bogotá: Banco de la República, Biblioteca V Centenario Colcultura.        [ Links ]

53. Harrison, J. P. (1969). The Colombian Tobacco Industry from Government Monopoly to Free Trade, 1778-1876. Bogotá: Centro de Estudios sobre Desarrollo Económico, Universidad de los Andes, Facultad de Economía.        [ Links ]

54. Havens, A. E., Montero, L. E., & Romieux, M. (1965). Cereté: un Área de Latifundio. Bogotá: Universidad Nacional de Colombia, Facultad de Sociología.        [ Links ]

55. Hettner, A. (1976). Viajes por los Andes Colombianos, 1882- 1884. Bogotá: Banco de la República.        [ Links ]

56. Hobsbawm, E., y Ranger, T. (1992). The Invention of Tradition. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.        [ Links ]

57. Holmes, G. K. (1916). Meat Situation in the United States. Part I. Statistics of Live Stock, Meat Production and Consumption, Prices, and International Trade for Many Countries. Washington: United States Department of Agriculture, Bureau of Crop Estimates.        [ Links ]

58. Holton, I. F. (1967). New Granada; Twenty Months in the Andes. Carbondale: Southern Illinois University Press.        [ Links ]

59. International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (IBRD). (1956). The Agricultural Development of Colombia. Washington: IBRD.        [ Links ]

60. Juan de Santa Gertrudis, F. (1994). Maravillas de la Naturaleza. Bogotá: Instituto Colombiano de Cultura.        [ Links ]

61. Jordan, T. G. (1993). North American Cattle-Ranching Frontiers: Origins, Diffusion, and Differentiation. Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press.        [ Links ]

62. Lagoeyte, A. (1918). Los Abonos en Colombia. Boletín Agrícola, 1(9), 376-378.        [ Links ]

63. León Mayorga, F., Arteaga Bocanegra, R. E., & Muñoz Vargas, M. A. (1975). Diagnóstico de la Situación Actual de la Industria Porcina en el Departamento del Tolima. Ibagué: Universidad del Tolima.        [ Links ]

64. Littman, E. L. (1965). Consideraciones sobre la Ganadería Porcina y el Mercado de la Carne de Cerdo en Colombia. Bogotá: Instituto Latinoaméricano de Mercadeo Agrícola.        [ Links ]

65. Londoño Mejía, G. (1935). Memoria del Ministerio de Agricultura y Comercio al Congreso Nacional en sus Sesiones Ordinarias de 1935. Bogotá: Imprenta Nacional.        [ Links ]

66. López, A. (1915). Antioquia: Monografía Estadística de este Departamento Colombiano. Medellín: Imprenta Oficial.        [ Links ]

67. Martínez C., A. (1990). Mesa y Cocina en el Siglo XIX. Bogotá: Planeta.        [ Links ]

68. Medina R., J. (1936). Geografía Económica de Colombia: Tomo III - Boyacá. Bogotá: Contraloría General de la República.        [ Links ]

69. Meisel R., A. & Vega A., M. (2004). La Estatura de los Colombianos: un Ensayo de Antropometría Histórica, 1910-2002. Documentos de Trabajo sobre Economía Regional, 45.        [ Links ]

70. Melville, E. (1994). A Plague of Sheep: Environmental Consequences of the Conquest of Mexico. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.        [ Links ]

71. Mennell, S. (1996). All Manners of Food: Eating and Taste in England and France from the Middle Ages to the Present. Urbana: University of Illinois Press.        [ Links ]

72. Ministerio de Agricultura (1968). Informe sobre la situación de las oleaginosas comestibles y sebos en Colombia. Bogotá: Ministerio de Agricultura.        [ Links ]

73. Molina Londoño, L. F. (2002). La Avicultura en Colombia. Bogotá: Fenavi, Fonav.        [ Links ]

74. Mollien, G.-T. (1992). Viaje por la República de Colombia en 7 823. Bogotá: Banco de la República, Biblioteca V Centenario Colcultura.

75. Monsalve, D. (1929). Monografía Estadística del Departamento de Antioquia. Medellín: Imprenta Oficial.        [ Links ]

76. Muñoz, L. & Hurtado, L. (1950). Alimentación de la Clase Obrera en Honda. Bogotá: Contraloría General, Dirección Nacional de Estadística.        [ Links ]

77. Negrete B., V. & Garabito, L. A. (1985). Puerto Libertador: Pasado y Presente. Montería: Fundación del Sinú.        [ Links ]

78. Nieto Arteta, L. E. (1996). Economía y Cultura en la Historia de Colombia. Bogotá: Banco de la República, Ancora Editores.        [ Links ]

79. Orlove, B. S. (1997). Meat and Strength: the Moral Economy of a Chilean Food Riot. Cultural Anthropology, 12(2), 1-35.        [ Links ]

80. Ospina O. G. (1940). La Explotación Económica del Cerdo. Bogotá: Editorial "El Gráfico".        [ Links ]

81. Ospina, T. (1913). Agricultura Colombiana: Notas de un Cur so Dictado en la Universidad de Antioquia. Medellín: La Familia Cristiana.        [ Links ]

82. Paris Lozano, G. (1946). Geografía Económica de Colombia: Tomo VII - Tolima. Bogotá: Contraloría.        [ Links ]

83. Parsons, J. J. (1968). Antioqueño Colonization in Western Colombia. Berkeley: University of California Press.        [ Links ]

84. Parsons, J. J. (1972). Spread of African Pasture Grasses to the American Tropics. Journal ofRange Management, 25, 12-17.        [ Links ]

85. Patiño, V. M. (2005). La Alimentación en Colombia y en los Países Vecinos. Cali: Universidad del Valle.        [ Links ]

86. Peñarete V. F. (1958). Geografía Económica de Cundinamar-ca. Tomo II. Bogotá: Contraloría de Cundinamarca.        [ Links ]

87. Pilcher, J. M. (2006). The Sausage Rebellion: Public Health, Private Enterprise, and Meat in Mexico City, 1890-1917. Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press.        [ Links ]

88. Posada, A. J. (1952). Economics of Colombian Agriculture. Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Dept. of Agricultural Economics, University of Wisconsin, Madison.        [ Links ]

89. Poveda, G. (1979). Agricultura y Ganadería Antioqueñas enel Siglo XIX. Revista Andi, 44, 99-132.        [ Links ]

90. Rausch,J. M. (1984).A Tropical Plains Frontier: the Llanos of Colombia, 1531-1831. Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press.        [ Links ]

91. Rausch, J. M. (1993). The Llanos Frontier in Colombian History, 1830-1930. Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press.        [ Links ]

92. Reinhardt, N. (1988). Our Daily Bread: the Peasant Question and Family Farming in the Colombian Andes. Berkeley: University of California Press.        [ Links ]

93. Restrepo Plata, F. (1912). La Agricultura en el Cauca. Revista Nacional de Agricultura, 7(11), 395-407.        [ Links ]

94. Restrepo Toro, L. F. (1988). La Porcicultura en Colombia. Bogotá: Corporación de Estudios Ganaderos y Agrícolas, Instituto Colombiano Agropecuario.        [ Links ]

95. Reyes Posada, A. (1978). Latifundio y Poder Político: La Hacienda Ganadera en Sucre. Bogotá: Editorial CINEP.        [ Links ]

96. Rifkin, J. (1992). Beyond Beef: the Rise and Fall of the CattleCulture. New York: Dutton.        [ Links ]

97. Rivas, M. (1983). Los Trabajadores de Tierra Caliente. Bogotá: Editorial Incunables.        [ Links ]

98. Rodríguez Guerrero, I. (1961). Geografía Económica de Nariño. Pasto: Editorial Sur Colombiana.        [ Links ]

99. Ruiz de Londoño, N. y Pinstrup-Anderson, P. (1975). Descripción de Factores Asociados con Bajos Rendimientos de Maíz en Fincas Pequeñas de Tres Departamentos de Colombia. Cali: CIAT.        [ Links ]

100. Saldarriaga, G. (2006). Consumo de Carnes en Zonas Cálidas del Nuevo Reino de Granada: Cualidades Cambiantes,Siglos XVI y XVII. Fronteras de la Historia, 11,17-52.        [ Links ]

101. Skaggs,J. M. (1986). Prime Cut: Livestock Raising and Meatpacking in the United States, 1607-1983. College Station:Texas A&M University Press.        [ Links ]

102. Sourdis Najera,A. (1996). Estructura de la Ganadería en el Caribe Colombiano durante el Siglo XVIII. Heullas, 47-48, 38-48.        [ Links ]

103. Striffler, L. (1980). El Río Sinú: Historia del Primer Establecimiento para Extracción de Oro en 1844. Cereté: Lino Editores.        [ Links ]

104. Striffler, S. (2005). Chicken: the Dangerous Transformation of America's Favorite Food. New Haven: Yale University Press.        [ Links ]

105. Taussig, M. (1977). The Evolution of Rural Wage Labor in the Cauca Valley of Colombia, 1700-1970. En: K. Duncan y I. Rutledge (Eds.), Land and Labour in Latin America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.        [ Links ]

106. Twigg, J. (1979). Food for Thought: Purity and Vegetaria-nism. Religion, 9(1), 131-135.        [ Links ]

107. U. S. Department of Commerce. (1975). Historical Statistics ofthe United States, Colonial Times to 1970 (Bicentennial ed.). Washington: U.S. Dept. of Commerce, Bureau of the Census.        [ Links ]

108. United Nations. (1962). Livestock in Latin America; Status, Problems and Prospects. I. Colombia, Mexico, Uruguay and Venezuela. New York: United Nations.        [ Links ]

109. United Nations. (1964). Livestock in Latin America; Status, Problems and Prospects. II. Brazil. New York: United Nations.        [ Links ]

110. Van Ausdal, S. (manuscript). Cattle, Power, and Profit: An Environmental History of Cattle Ranching in Colombia, 1850-1950. Submitted to Geoforum.        [ Links ]

111. Van Ausdal, S. (forthcoming). Un Mosaico Cambiante: Notas Sobre una Geografía Histórica de la Ganadería en Colombia, 1850-1950. En: A. Flórez (Ed.), El Poder de la Carne: Historias de Ganaderías en la Primera Mitad del Siglo XX en Colombia. Bogotá: Universidad Javeriana.        [ Links ]

112. Varela Martínez, R. (1952). Economía Agropecuaria de Colombia en 1950. Bogotá: Ministerio de Agricultura, División de Economía Rural.        [ Links ]

113. Vargas, P. F. de & Forero, M. J. (1944). Pensamientos Políticos y Memoria sobre la Población del Nuevo Reino de Granada. Bogotá: Biblioteca Popular de Cultura Colombiana.        [ Links ]

114. Walsh, M. (1977). Pork Packing as a Leading Edge of Mid-western Industry, 1835-1875. Agricultural History, 51(4), 702-717.        [ Links ]

115. Watson, J. L. y Caldwell, M. L. (2005). The Cultural Politics of Food and Eating: a Reader. Malden, MA: Blackwell.        [ Links ]

116. West, R. C. (1952). Colonial Placer Mining in Colombia. Baton Rouge: Louisiana State University Press.        [ Links ]

117. Wylie, K. H. (1942). The Agriculture of Colombia. Foreign Agricultural Bulletin, 1 (October), 1-160.        [ Links ]

Fecha de recepción: 21 de noviembre de 2007 • Fecha de modificación: 17 de diciembre de 2007 • Fecha de aceptación: 23 de enero de 2008

Creative Commons License All the contents of this journal, except where otherwise noted, is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution License